="http://www.w3.org/2000/svg" viewBox="0 0 512 512">

5 The American Congress and the Legislative Process

Learning Objectives

  1. Explain the significance of the differences between the American Congress and parliamentary systems of government.
  2. Explain how federal law and Supreme Court decisions shape voting and representation in Congress.
  3. Explain the factors that contribute to “the incumbency advantage” in Congressional elections.
  4. Explain the factors that, in addition to the incumbency advantage, shape Congressional elections.
  5. Explain the role of party leaders and Congressional committees.
  6. Explain “agenda setting” in Congress using the Wilson “grid.”
  7. Explain the significance of “pivotal legislators” in Congress.
  8. Explain the major differences between the “textbook Congress” and the “hyper-partisan” Congress.

I. Congress vs. Parliament

Congress, the American bi-cameral legislature consisting of the House and Senate, has had a public relations problem for quite some time. In 2017, President Trump’s approval rating has hovered around 40%; during much of the past decade, the public approval of Congress has hovered around 20%. This is reflected in much scholarly commentary on Congress as well. Congressional scholars Thomas Mann and Norman Ornstein published a book entitled The Broken Branch in 2006, when Congress was controlled by Democrats; their subsequent book, written when the House had returned to Republican control, was entitled It is Even Worse than it Looks.1 In these works, Congress was portrayed as a dysfunctional institution in which the individual representatives and Senators were more concerned with their own electoral fate than with public policy, rational deliberation was subordinated to extreme partisanship, and Congressional responsibility within the system of separated powers had been diminished. Not all of these criticisms and observations were particularly new.2 This may suggest that Congress has always been uniquely dysfunctional. Yet there are different ways of interpreting the supposedly dysfunctional character of Congress. It may be the case that Congress, despite its apparent dysfunction and inefficiency, is well-suited to a deeply-divided society, one in which there are fundamental disagreements over what government should do, and how it should go about doing it.

Many criticisms of of the American Congress are based on the assumption that parliamentary forms of government are preferable to the American system, characterized by the separation of powers between the executive and the legislative branch, and a bi-cameral legislative system. The consequences of these institutional differences shape nearly all aspects of politics. One way to think about the differences is to compare them to different forms fighting: parliamentary systems of government are like boxing matches (or, perhaps, mixed martial arts contests), while the American separation of powers system is like a bar fight. In a boxing match, there are clear sides, clear rules, and a clear winner– this is usually, though not always, the pattern reflected in parliamentary politics. The election is the main “fight,” and it produces a government that is clearly in charge, in the sense of being responsible for law and policy.3 In a bar fight, however, no one is quite sure how or when the conflict begins, the sides are often amorphous and possibly changing, it is difficult to tell when or if a victory has been achieved, there is a great deal of screaming and anger, and in the end someone is likely to get sued. That captures the spirit of the American system. It may be well suited for the American people.

That parliamentary governments are in some ways like a boxing match does not mean that the powers of the “victors” in parliamentary governments are unconstrained. Even majority governments must look ahead to the next election; the opposition party provides a constant running commentary and critique that the government must take into account; in what is increasingly a common situation in parliamentary government, different parties must cooperate to form coalition governments. The notion of “responsibility” helps to convey the underlying purposes of parliamentary practice. The phrase “responsible government” has a simple meaning: the executive branch, controlled by the Prime Minister and Cabinet, is responsible to the House of Commons; ministers are selected from the House of Commons, and maintain their position by virtue of the continued support of the House, as shown in their support for major pieces of legislation sponsored by the government. Just as importantly, in a parliamentary system of government, “we the people” know who is responsible for government policy. Federal government spending in Canada is, as of January 4th 2018, the responsibility of the Liberal government under Prime Minister Justin Trudeau. Parliamentary systems of government let us know, with admirable clarity, who is responsible for the creation of law, and who is responsible and therefore accountable for implementing public policy. There are some disadvantages to concentrating power in this way, but without a doubt, it makes the lines of responsibility perfectly apparent.

The lines of responsibility are not so clear in American politics. It would not be correct to say, for instance, that President Obama was responsible for the details of the “Affordable Care Act” in the same way that the Conservative government under Prime Minister Harper was responsible for Bill C-51.4 In practice, the roles of Presidents and Prime Ministers are very different. Laws in the United States– any complex or controversial law— are only passed after an extended and often chaotic campaign to mobilize and maintain support. This is because, in the American system, political parties have not developed the power of party discipline, the power to compel individual members of party to support legislative proposals, regardless of their own beliefs or the interests of their constituents. Achieving major policy reforms in the absence of party discipline really is like trying to win a bar fight. There are occasions in which the American system can mimic the cohesiveness and decisiveness of parliamentary regimes. There are instances when parties achieve sweeping electoral victories, establish clear mandates for political change, and enact political change because the party is not divided by serious internal ideological divisions. Those periods are relatively rare. The Constitutional system was designed to make it difficult for any one party to achieve or maintain complete control over national government power, and this institutional bias has been reinforced by the size, diversity, and fractiousness of the American people. We might conclude that this form of government encourages deliberation and cooperation, while inhibiting the power of tyrannical majorities. Yet we might also conclude that the system produces stalemate and gridlock. Both viewpoints are worth considering, as both are partially correct.

The most important difference between Parliament and Congress is that individual legislators in Congress have a considerable degree of power and influence. This distinguishes the American Congress from almost every other legislature in the world, not merely the Canadian House of Commons. Legislators are powerful in the American political system because parties are weak, as American parties have only a limited ability to insure the loyalty of individual legislators. A disciplined party votes as a team, because the party as a whole has the ability to punish defectors by removing them from the party. This weapon does not exist in American politics. Party discipline exists within Congress, to some extent, but it is not the only factor which determines how legislators vote. For instance, there are many reasons why Democratic legislators might wish to follow the lead of their President or of party leaders in Congress.5 There are many reasons why GOP legislators will wish to support Speaker of the House Paul Ryan or Majority Leader of the Senate Mitch McConnell. Should they decide otherwise, however, it is difficult for their leaders to control them.

Why is this the case? Why is the American legislature more chaotic, more individualistic, but also more influential than legislatures in most Parliamentary systems?American parties are often “weak” in the legislative process because the Constitution separates the executive (the President) from the legislature, and establishes specific election dates. The executive does not require the support of the legislature to remain in power, and therefore the incentive for maintaining party discipline in the American political system was never as strong as in Parliamentary system. The separation of the legislative and executive branch is thus the primary institutional cause of the limited party discipline in the American political order. It is true that, during some periods of time, parties exercise significant influence over their members.6 However, the rise of direct primaries, the development of fund-raising and communication tools that enable candidate centered campaigning, and the decline in the power of party leaders in the House and Senate all reduced the ability of parties to control their members. Primaries allow members of Congress to take their political fate into their own hands—and members of Congress spend a great deal of time developing formidable campaign organizations that enable them to do just that. Possessing these resources, individual legislators need not heed the dictates of party leadership—they can consult the wishes and interests of their constituents, or the dictates of their own conscience. As a consequence, party leaders cannot simply present legislative proposals to the legislature and expect perfect agreement and complete support from their party’s members; individual members of Congress insist on playing a major role in developing legislative proposals, in contrast with most parliamentary systems where law- making is dominated by the executive and executive-branch bureaucracies.7

We should note, however, that the degree of party unity in Congress varies over time. This can be seen by looking at “party unity votes” over time (a party unity vote is a vote in which a majority of Democrats vote against a majority of Republicans.)

Figure 5.1: Party Unity Scores in Congress, 1953-20178

Under some circumstances, Congress will behave in a more “parliamentary” fashion, even though party leaders do not have the same ability to influence Senators and House members as do parliamentary leaders Understanding the changing role of parties and party leaders is one of the most important things to consider when trying to understand how Congress operates, and it is one of the most important distinguishing features of the American legislative process. There are other major recurring features of Congress that are just as important– some of which are closely connected to the institutional structure created by the Constitution, some of which have developed as a kind of organic outgrowth of the Constitution.

II. Representation, Voting, and Elections

The American Congress and the Canadian Parliament are both representative institutions. But what does it mean for an institution to be “representative”? Representative government is simply a form of government in which one part of society “stands in for” or “re-presents” the public. In the United States and Canada, representation takes place through a democratic process– citizens play a role in selecting individuals who will represent them in Congress or the House of Commons. Though there is some agreement over what it means for a system of representation to be democratic, there is considerable disagreement over what should occur in the process of representation. Some political thinkers have argued that, as far as possible, a legislature should be like a miniature version of society– the demographic characteristics of the individuals who make up the legislature should reflect, in a general way, the demographic characteristics of society as a whole.9 Though some of the founding fathers of the American political system expressed support for the idea of descriptive representation, the American constitution does not attempt to establish it directly. Indirectly, the Constitution creates a certain degree of “descriptive representation” in the House and Senate, for the simple reason that representation is based upon geography. Though there is no way to insure that all groups are represented equally, Congress has always been made up of a geographically diverse group of individuals. Indeed, James Madison thought that this was a crucial benefit of the “extended sphere” of the American republic, as he assumed that economic interests were closely tied to geography. In a society of sufficient geographic size, with a system of representation based upon place (that is, states or congressional districts), there would be no dominant economic interest within Congress. Unsurprisingly, however, Senators and Representatives have tended to come from the relatively well-off segment of society; lawyers are vastly overrepresented amongst the political class as well. In terms of its general make-up, the American Congress does not reflect the full demographic diversity of the nation. Yet over time Congress has become closer to being a “miniature” reflection of society. For instance, in the 115th Congress (the current Congress), there are 45 African members of the House, slightly more than 10% of the total number of seats; African Americans constitute approximately 13% of the populations of the United States as a whole.

It is not clear whether descriptive representation is an essential element of democracy, in that a group can still influence politics even its own members do not hold political office. If a group is part of a political coalition, and if its political power is acknowledged and respected by elected officials and its political preferences taken into account, it may not matter if the group is not represented by one of its own members.10 Effective representation may simply require that the elected official act as an effective delegate for those they represent. Others suggest that effective representation does not even require officials to follow the opinions and preferences of their constituents in all circumstances. According to this trusteeship theory of representation, elected officials can and should exercise their own independent judgment when exercising their public duties, at least under some conditions. Effective representation requires not slavish devotion to public opinion (or the opinion of some sub-set of the public) but rather a certain degree of autonomy for political decision-makers.

The electoral system of the United States reflects the descriptive, delegate, and trusteeship dimensions of representation. One obvious obstacle to descriptive representation in the USA is that, for much of American history, individuals could be denied the vote on the basis of their class, race, ethnicity or gender.11 The original Constitution allowed states to set voting requirements as they saw fit12, and some states restricted the right to vote (or “the franchise”) to property-owning white males. Property restrictions on voting for white males gradually died out in the early part of the nineteenth century, while voting rights for white women were enshrined at the national level in 1920 through the adoption of the nineteenth amendment.13 Voting rights for African Americans took much longer to establish.

Voting rights for African Americans, particularly but not only in the South, would not receive adequate protections from the federal government until the 1960s. It is for this reason that some scholars claim that the United States did not really become a democracy until the final third of the twentieth century. Though the fifteenth amendment had guaranteed African Americans the right to vote, by the end of the nineteenth century the Republican party had more or less abandoned the attempt to insure that the formal right to vote could be exercised in practice. The most important step towards universalizing the right to vote came with the passage of the Voting Rights Act of 1965. The main purpose of the Voting Rights Act was to insure that African Americans were not prevented from exercising their voting rights. Prior to the 1960s, many Southern states had used various devices to prevent blacks from voting. For instance, fraudulent “literacy tests” were applied to African Americans, but not to whites. As late as the 1960s, in some Southern counties, blacks were given questions about the number of bubbles in a soap bar as part of these tests. The voting rights act empowered the national government to prevent these forms of discrimination.

Supreme Court decisions shaped voting rights in other instances, most notably in relation to the reapportionment revolution initiated in the case of Baker v. Carr (1962). “Apportionment” refers to the ways in which states draw up or “apportion” legislative districts; reapportionment (also called redistricting) usually occurs after the decennial American census, and in theory the redrawing of district lines is meant to take into account changes in population distribution alone. In practice, redistricting can often be used for political purposes– to support a political party, or to reduce to power of particular racial and ethnic groups. In the case of Baker v. Carr, the court ruled that state legislative districts had to have roughly equal numbers of voters– districts could not be “malapportioned” in the legislative branch– and this ruling was extended, through other cases, to Congressional districts as well. This is a good example of how a principle– the principle of equal voting power, summarized inaccurately through the catchphrase “one person, one vote”– became incorporated into Constitutional law even though it has little to do with the Constitution. How do we know that equal voting power is not one of the fundamental principles of the American constitution? The Senate and the Electoral College do not distribute “voting power” in an equal manner. Nevertheless, some judicial innovations become accepted over time, and this is one of those cases.

While courts could equalize Congressional districts, they could not supervise the more subterranean forms of voter discrimination that had emerged in American politics– thus the need for the Voting Rights Act, which allowed the federal government to supervise electoral practices at the state level.14 While the general purpose of the Act was undoubtedly constitutional, the means chosen to implement the policy were somewhat unusual. The most obvious way to implement the policy would be to create the rule– no discrimination in voting– and then allow the Justice Department to prosecute suspected violators. This was done, but more was done as well. The law imposed a “pre-clearance” requirement on many states, which meant that changes in voting regulations had to be “pre-cleared” or approved by the Justice Department. Thus the law seemed to create a new legislative procedure, in which the federal government had a veto over the law-making power of some states. It was definitely cheaper and easier than relying on investigations and prosecutions alone. The Supreme Court shrugged its shoulders, on the grounds that it is acceptable to unofficially amend the Constitution if it is convenient. The argument is bad from a legal perspective, though understandable and maybe even justified from a political perspective.

Voter registration for African Americans went up dramatically as a consequence of these changes. (E.g. from 7% voter registration for African Americans in Miss. in 1960 to over 60% by the end of the decade.) The right to vote is not the same thing as the right to elect the candidate of your choice, of course. Over time, the Justice Department became more concerned with the question of voting effectiveness, usually understood in terms of descriptive representation. Through a variety of means, the federal government required states to create “majority-minority” districts in order to prevent the “dilution” of African American votes. The assumption here was that states– at least some states, typically in the south– should be forced to draw district lines so as to group black voters together, so as to increase the likelihood of representation of African American voters by African American officials. The Voting Rights Act, as interpreted by the federal Justice department, interpreted effective representation as descriptive representation.15

From a political perspective, the creation of majority-minority districts raises some interesting issues. Consider this: the Republican party was gaining strength in the South during this period; given this fact, why did it often support the use of “race-based” districting? The answer is that the Republican Party often benefited from having African American voters concentrated in a smaller number of districts, as this made it easier for the Republican party to win in white-majority districts. Majority-minority districting has weakened the Democrats at all political levels in the South, even though it has obviously increased the number of African American legislators.

From a constitutional perspective, the use of race to create majority-minority districts has led to some baffling Supreme Court decisions. The case of Shaw v. Reno from 1994, for instance, did not exactly prohibit race-based districting, but in invalidating a district that was specifically designed to be have a majority of African Americans, the ruling seemed to conclude that race shouldn’t be used “too much.” This case dealt with a district which had a “strange shape;” some parts of the district were no wider than a highway. The problem is that there is no constitutional right to geometrically pleasing congressional districts. Compact and contiguous districts might be important for all kinds of reasons, but they are not required by anything actually written in the Constitution.

Voting rights remain a highly contested issue, as recent Supreme Court decisions such as Shelby County v. Holder demonstrate. This case dealt with the power of “pre-clearance”– the power of the federal Justice Department to approve all changes in voting requirements made by state that had previously engaged in widespread disenfranchisement of racial minorities. The court ruled, in a 5-4 decision, that the practice of pre-clearance could not be applied to only some states, based upon discriminatory practices that had occurred forty years in the past. As a consequence, a larger number of states have been able to change voting rules– abandoning same-day voter registration, for instance, or by tightening voter identification requirements- in ways that could have an impact on the voting rates of blacks and other minorities.

In addition to state-level regulation of the right to vote, state governments are also responsible for drawing legislative districts for the House– the process of “reapportionment.” As discussed above, re-apportionment normally takes place after every official census of the American population (which takes place every ten years.) The 435 congressional districts of the United States then have to be adjusted to take into account shifts in population; states with declining population may have the size of their Congressional delegation reduced, and the district lines may have to be adjusted to make sure that all districts have equal populations. However, as the process of reapportionment is controlled by state legislators, it is not surprising that districts are often drawn with political considerations in mind– this is known as “gerrymandering.” Gerrymandering is simply the process of drawing district lines so as to maximize your own party’s number of seats. This can be done by “cracking” your opponents’ supporters into multiple districts, thereby diluting their impact on elections. It can also be done by “packing” the supporters of the opposing party into as few districts as possible; in those districts, your opponents are likely to win, but many of the votes they receive will have been unnecessary to achieve victory.

Under current conditions, Republicans benefit from gerrymandering because of their power in state legislatures– in the 2016 election, this means that the GOP received 55% of the seats in the House of Representatives despite receiving only 49% of the vote. The Supreme Court has never ruled that partisan gerrymandering is unconstitutional, yet it has suggested that some kinds of partisan gerrymandering may be unacceptable. Some scholars have suggested that court can use the concept of “the efficiency gap” as a standard to evaluate congressional districting.16 The efficiency gap is determined by calculating the relationship between a party’s “wasted votes” (the number of votes above 50% in districts where it has achieved electoral victories) and the total number of votes. To use this measure as a standard for evaluating the constitutionality of legislative districting, the Supreme Court will have to determine an efficiency gap threshold– perhaps the long-term average, which is around 6%. Almost two dozen states have tried to address the problem of Congressional districting by allowing non-partisan or bi-partisan commissions to manage redistricting.

III. Elections in the House and Senate– The Decision to Run, Primaries, and General Elections

Running for election in the House and Senate is a daunting process. It is costly, time-consuming, and likely to end in failure. The reason for this is rather simple: particularly in regards to the House of Representatives, incumbents (those who already hold office) tend to win re-election. This is known as the incumbency advantage. It is reflected in the high re-election rates for incumbents in House and Senate elections.

Figure 5.2: US House Reelection Rates, 1964-2016

Figure 5.3: US Senate Reelection Rates, 1964-2016

Re-election rates for the Senate are high, though they are not as high as in the House.

The possible causes of the incumbency are easy enough to identify, though it is difficult to determine precisely whether the incumbency advantage results from the advantages of incumbents or the disadvantages of challengers. Perhaps the greatest advantage for those who already hold elected office is that many Congressional districts are not very politically competitive. In the 2016 House election, only 10 races out of 435 had a margin of victory of less than 5%.17 In terms of political beliefs, Americans are more “sorted” by geography than at almost any time in the past. In the 2016 Presidential election, 60% of Americans lived in counties where the margin of victory for either Trump or Clinton was more than 20%.18 In 1976, only 26 percent of the population lived in a “landslide county”.19 Yet even though the results of many House elections are determined well before election, there are years in which major shifts can occur. The most prominent recent example is the mid-term elections of 2010, in which the Democrats lost 63 seats in the House and 53 Democratic incumbents were defeated. Though the country may be more politically sorted than in the past, this does not mean that “battleground” districts have disappeared. In fact, the struggle for control of the House and Senate is much more uncertain in the 21st century than it was for most of the 20th century, even though many incumbents reside in relatively safe districts.

In addition to advantages derived from political geography, incumbents also have personal characteristics that make them difficult to challenge. Incumbents almost always have an advantage in terms of name recognition and fundraising, two very valuable resources in elections.20 Incumbents also have access to the perquisites that come from holding office– resources that they can use to mail material to their constituents, travel budgets that allow them to spend time amongst their constituents, and congressional staff budgets that can further facilitate electoral activities. The ability to communicate and establish familiarity with constituents, famously called the “home-style” of Congressional representatives by the great student of Congress Richard Fenno, has been identified by many scholars as one of the most important sources of the incumbency advantage.21 Technological changes may have contributed to the incumbency advantage as well– according to some scholars, the rise of local television stations in the 1960s and 1970s may have helped Congressional incumbents, as these new media outlets provided additional media coverage to elected representatives.22 These advantages– name recognition, access to media coverage, fundraising, institutional resources of Congressional office– increase the incumbent’s advantages in two main ways. Incumbents are simply able to perform better in the electoral arena, and their resources (particularly their ability to raise vast amounts of money) tend to scare away or intimidate high-quality challengers. Thus even though most Congressional elections are contested, many challengers are political amateurs with little chance of victory.

Given the difficulty and cost of running for election, candidates for House and Senate seats have to be strategic when making a decision to run for office. Often, the best opportunity for new candidates comes when a member of Congress chooses to retire, thus creating an “open seat.” If the state or district leans heavily towards either the Democrats or Republicans, winning the primary will often be more difficult than winning the general election, though this is more likely to be true for House races than for the Senate. It is also the case that opportunities can arise if one of the two parties is encountering a significant decline in public support. While control of Congress was relatively stable between 1932 and 1992, in the previous twenty five years control of the House and Senate has shifted in 1994( the GOP took control of the House and Senate) 2000 (Democrats control the Senate) , 2002 (GOP takes control of the Senate), 2006 (Democrats take control of the House and Senate), 2010 (GOP takes control of the House), and 2014 (GOP takes control of the Senate.)

The decision to run for Congress is to a considerable extent an individual decision; particularly during the primaries, candidates have to rely on their own organizational skills and fundraising acumen to get their campaigns off the ground. Challengers that face long-established incumbents in non-competitive districts or states will often have little more than a bare-bones campaign organization. Competitive seats will usually attract `higher quality`candidates, whether individuals who have their own resources to devote to an election campaign, or individuals who have the experience and connections to raise significant amounts of money.

It is increasingly common for congressional elections, and even congressional primaries, to attract a significant amount of outside spending– spending by independent organizations such as Political Action Committees (PACs), as well as spending by national party committees. Consider, for instance, the case of California district 7, which is located in the North-Central part of the state near Sacramento. In 2014, Democrat Ami Bera won an open seat election in the district, but by a margin of less than 1,500 votes (out of more than 180,000 cast.)23 Unsurprisingly, both parties recognized that the seat would be highly contested in 2016. The Republican candidate, Scott Jones, had been elected sheriff in Sacramento county in 2010, and his campaign emphasized the differences in political views between Jones, Donald Trump, and the conservative “mainstream” of the Republican party ( a matter of necessity in northern California.) Jones, in other words, was a high-quality candidate who had political and electoral experience in the region, and he had a reasonable hope of achieving victory. As a consequence, the candidates raised significant amounts of money for their own campaigns: while the average House campaign raises around $500,000, Bera was able to raise $4,078,146 while his opponent raised $1,354,519. The race was also one of nineteen races in which “outside spending` (more than $8,000,000) was greater than spending by the candidates` campaign organizations (around $5,000,000). Thus while candidates do have to rely on their own fundraising abilities and even personal wealth, political organizations such as PACs and national party committees play a crucial role in many races, particularly closely contested seats.24

National party committees also play a role in recruiting and training candidates. The “Hill Committees” are partisan organizations that are focussed on electing members of the House and Senate; the hill committees are the National Republican Senate Committee, the Democratic Senate Campaign Committee, the National Republican Congressional Committee, and the Democratic Congressional Campaign Committee. These committees are distinct from Democratic National Committee and the Republican National Committee, which are the formal governing bodies of the national parties which try to coordinate strategy across all levels of local, state, and national politics.

While “Hill committees” attempt to recruit, train, and promote viable candidates, it is crucial to remember that parties have limited ability to select, control, or even influence candidates This is because candidate are selected through primary elections– the most unusual aspect of American electoral politics from a comparative perspective. Try as they might, primary elections obviously make it impossible for party elites to determine who will run for office. The problem is that some candidates who are successful in primary elections are not the most likely to succeed in the general election. This occurs for a very simply reason: voter participation in primary elections is often quite low, and voters in primary elections tend to be more ideologically extreme than other voters aligned with the party.25

This dynamic was on display in the `Tea Party` mid-term election of 2010. The “Tea Party” refers to a largely disorganized social movement that developed over the course the 2009-2010 electoral cycle; there was never any formal Tea Party organization at the national level, and there were no specific requirements for being part of the movement. In general, however, members of the movement were motivated by dissatisfaction with the Republican Party, particularly the GOP’s response to the financial crisis of 2008, the support that the Republican establishment had shown for immigration reform, and the failure to control spending during the George W. Bush era.26 The main short-term tactic of the Tea Party movement was to challenge moderate Republicans in primary elections. From the perspective of the Republican Party establishment, this led to some unfortunate consequences: several Tea Party associated candidates, such as Sharron Angle in Nevada, Christine O’Donnell in Delaware, lost Senate elections that probably could have been won by more moderate candidates. The influence of the Tea Party in these key Senatorial primaries may have cost the Republicans control of the Senate.

While American parties lack the formal ability to control who runs for Congress, there are strategies that they can employ to shape primary elections. Consider the case of the 2014 Congressional mid-terms. The Republican Party was still facing challenges from the inchoate Tea Party movement, but incumbents were more adept at responding to the challenges. Lindsay Graham, Republican Senator from South Carolina, responded to the spectre of a Tea Party challenge in the primary by making highly visible criticisms of the Obama administration, particularly in regards to the Benghazi scandal. Other incumbents were able to fend off primary challenges in a similar manner, though many also benefited from divided opposition. Even so, these were some serious casualties amongst the mainstream Republican party during the primary season. The most startling case was the defeat of House Majority leader Eric Cantor by upstart immigration restrictionist Dave Brat– a result that was anticipated by very few. This is probably the best example of how parties are unable to control their membership; even incumbents who are firmly ensconced in the party’s government hierarchy can suddenly find themselves thrown out of office by the “party in the electorate.”

There are three general categories of factors that shape the outcome of Congressional elections: money and resources, organization and strategy, and background conditions (such as the state of the economy). We begin, as congressional candidate must, with the question of raising money. Congressional elections are not necessarily determined through money alone, but it is nevertheless the case that the ability to raise money is a necessary (though not sufficient) condition for electoral victory. Though federal laws (most importantly, the 2002 Bi-Partisan Campaign Finance Act) place many limits on donations to political campaigns, individual candidates can spend an unlimited amount of their own money in pursuit of electoral office. This can often be a futile exercise– in the 2016 electoral cycle, David Trone of Maryland lost the primary for House seat, even though he spent more than $13 million dollars of his own money. In the 2016 general election, some self-financing candidate lost a huge amount of money. Randy Perkins, running In Florida’s 18th district, spent 10 million dollars of his own money in a losing bid to win an open seat, an amount of money that was three times the amount spent by the victor Brian Mast.27 This provides yet another example of the complex relationship between campaign spending and electoral outcomes; just as promotional campaigns cannot always rescue a horrible movie, dumping huge amounts of money into a political campaign cannot rescue a flawed candidate, or overcome the underlying political dynamics of a Congressional district.

While candidates can spend (or waste) as much of their own money as they like on their campaigns, donations by individuals to political campaigns are regulated by campaign finance laws. These donations are often called “hard money” donations (though donations from individuals are not the only type of “hard money.”) Currently, individuals can donate $2500 per election to a candidate. Another major source of hard-money donations are “Political Action Committees” or PACs; these are organizations that raise and spend money in elections. The top spending PACs are dominated by business associations and unions, and they can donate up to $5000 to a candidate per election. Another source of “hard money” direct donations comes from the above-mentioned political party “Hill committees,” as well as from state and local committees.

Table 5.1: “Hard Money” Donations to House Elections, 2016 electoral Cycle (Primaries and General Election)
Party # candidates Individual Donations PAC Donations
Democrats 908 $275,105,347 $151,287,745
Republicans 1074 $276,463,148 $211,319,899
Table 5.2: “Hard Money” Donations to House Elections, 2016 electoral Cycle (Primaries and General Election)
Party #candidates Individual Donations PAC Donations
Democrats 170 $286,750,451 $45,139,886
Republicans 230 $193,036,593 $70,597,456

Source: https://www.opensecrets.org/overview/index.php?display=T&type=A&cycle=2016

Not all money spent in election campaigns will be spent by the candidates themselves. “Super-PACs” or “independent expenditure only” are organizations that can raise unlimited amounts of money and spend unlimited amounts of money advocating for particular candidates, criticizing particular candidates, or addressing particular causes. In contrast with ordinary PACs, the “super” versions cannot actually donate to particular candidates, and in addition, they cannot coordinate their campaign-related activities with candidate committees. Famously, or infamously, the Supreme Court has played a major role in lifting restrictions on Super -PAC fundraising and spending. In the case of Citizens’ United v. United States, the court ruled in a narrow decision that the primary justification for campaign finance laws was to prevent corruption; therefore, while this would justify limits on direct donations to candidates, it does not justify limits on other types of political communication. If the independent expenditure related provisions of the BCRA had been allowed to stand, the government would have had the power to regulate any film, book, newspaper, or advertisement created by any corporation. Some claimed that this conferred rights on corporations, rights which they do not possess because they are not individual persons; this is correct, however, it isn’t clear why groups of people should be denied rights merely because because they choose to take advantage of the corporate form of organization.

There are two other general kinds of organizations that are also engaged in Congressional election spending spree, both named after the relevant sections of the U.S. Tax Code: Section 527 organizations and Section 501(c)4 organizations. Section 527 organizations, unlike Super-PACs, cannot advocate on behalf or against particular parties or candidates. Section 501(c)4s are tax-exempt “social welfare” organizations that can spend money on political causes such as issue advocacy, as long as political advocacy is not the primary purpose of the organization; these organizations are sometimes referred to as “dark money” organizations, because they are not required to reveal information about their donors. The National Rifle Association, Planned Parenthood, and the Sierra Club are examples of well-known 501(c)4 organizations.

What is the ultimate impact of all of this money– whether the highly regulated “hard money” that goes directly to candidate campaign committees, or the largely unregulated “soft money” spent in the electoral cycle by Super-PACs, 527s, and 501(c)4 organizations? If we restrict ourselves to the electoral process, it is difficult to know the exact impact of campaign spending, whether in the hard or soft form. As noted above, and as demonstrated by the Presidential election of 2016, a candidate’s campaign can have a massive fundraising advantage and yet still lose the election. Beyond that, it is difficult to give a precise answer to the effect of money in the electoral process. It is, however, rather easy to explain why it is so difficult to assess the impact of money in Congressional elections. Incumbents tend to win re-election, and they also tend to raise more money than challengers; does the advantage in campaign spending allow the incumbents to win, or does the fact that they are likely win reelection allow them to raise additional money? Incumbents have many advantages that have little to with campaign spending– they may come a district or state that favours their party, they may have proven themselves to be effective advocates for the interests of their constituents, they may have established name-recognition through years or even decades of political service. When challengers achieve victory, it is similarly to difficult to isolate the independent effects of money on electoral outcomes, because the quality of the challenge is not independent of the amount of money raised by the challenger. The effect of money on elections, in other words, depends upon a host of factors. 28 Even if we continue to think that money determines electoral outcomes, we should be consoled by the fact that, in general, the main political parties and their interest groups allies. are roughly equal in their ability to raise money. This is not to suggest that money does not influence American politics, but it is to suggest that the electoral process is not completely distorted by campaign spending.

IV. How Congress is Organized

Congress consists of 535 legislators– 435 members of the House, and 100 Senators. While these legislators are largely responsible for their own electoral fortunes, and even though they have far more independence than legislators in parliamentary forms of government, it is still necessary for Congress to organize itself if it wishes to accomplish anything. There are three major dimensions of Congressional organization– the constitutional dimension (the separation of the House and the Senate as separate legislative chambers), partisan organization (which is primarily about organizing parties within the House and Senate in order to set a legislative agenda and pass bills), committee organization (which is primarily about dividing up policy authority into specialized sub-units, thereby allowing the legislative branch to benefit from the division of labour, and allowing individual legislators to develop policy expertise. )

a) Bi-Cameralism: The House vs. The Senate

The most striking feature of Congress is that it is a bi-cameral legislature, with an “upper house” that in no way sees itself as being less legitimate than the lower house (in contrast with the Canadian Senate, of course.)29 The purpose of the Senate, as James Madison elaborates in Federalist Paper #62, is to make it difficult to create law. If you have two legislative bodies who must come to agreement before a law is passed, and if those legislative bodies are selected based upon different principles (representation by population versus representation by state), and if the time-frame of elections differs (every two years versus staggered six year terms) then there are likely to be important differences between the interests and perspective of the two bodies. It will be difficult for them to come to agreement, particularly in regards to contentious issues. In this way the Constitution places obstacles in the path of the majority, though not insuperable obstacles. 30

Consider the shift in public opinion that occurred in 2010. Through a combination of economic stagnation, depressed voter turnout for the Democrats, and the mobilization of the Tea Party which shook up the GOP establishment and energized conservative voters, there was a massive shift in seats in the House of Representatives: the GOP won 63 seats, the largest shift in House elections since 1948. Yet despite this massive shift, there was not even a complete shift of power within Congress; despite winning six additional seats, which presumably reflects at least some change in public opinion, the GOP could not take control of the Senate. The Constitution makes it difficult for short term changes in public opinion to change the balance of power in Washington, and the Senate plays a key role in this dynamic. Taking over the Senate is a long-term process. Only 1/3 of the Senate comes up for election every two years. When only 1/3 of the Senate seats are up for grabs, it is obviously difficult to translate short term shifts in public sentiment to shifts in control of the Senate.

The structure of elections can lead to tension between the House and Senate. What about the differences in constituency? The Senate is apportioned by state; every state, no matter how small and weird, is given two Senators; the House of Representatives is based upon representation by population. To what extent does regional representation affect legislative politics in the USA? On the one hand, the “small state” bias of the Senate works in favour of the Republican Party31; smaller states are typically more rural states, and while this may have helped some Democrats during the days of William Jennings Bryan and prairie populism, today rural voters tend to support the Republican Party. Consider as well that the smallest 25 states have approximately 58 million residents out of a total population of 318 million; theoretically, therefore, Senators representing a small fraction of the nation could thwart the wishes of national majorities (though one should note that the interests and politics of small states are far from uniform—it is very difficult to think of a contemporary issue that would unite small states against large states, other than a proposal to eliminate equal state representation in the Senate.) However, it is common for bills to be voted down by Senate majorities that do not represent popular majorities—for example, the immigration reform bill that was voted down in the Senate in 2007.32

Not surprisingly, political scientists are in some disagreement over the question of whether the Senate gives a decisive political advantage to the Republican Party. Yale political scientist David Mayhew argues that the GOP’s advantage is small, and is offset in the contemporary era by the presence of a not insignificant number of small, Democrat leaning states such as Hawaii.33 However, other scholars suggest that the interests of small states often play a disproportionate role; for instance, some have speculated that the Senate has opposed climate change initiatives because low population rural states often rely on fossil fuels more than urbanized states.34 Just as the differing modes of election can produce tensions between the House and the Senate, the differing constituencies of the House and the Senate can be a source of disagreement and gridlock.

b) Party Organization, Party Leaders, and Caucuses in Congress

Parties play a role in Congress that is in some ways the same as parties in parliamentary regimes– the parties are “teams” of like-minded individuals who ban together in order to select leaders, set the legislative agenda, and manage the legislative process. The most obvious difference between parties in the American Congress and parties in parliamentary regimes like Canada is that Congressional parties do not actually select the executive (except under what have proven to be very unusual circumstances. Congressional parties do select leadership positions within Congress, however. Whether through the Republican conference or the Democratic caucus (the names that the parties give to their collective members in Congress), the majority party in the House and Senate elect candidates for the two most important position in Congress: the Speaker of the House, and the majority leader of the Senate. The House majority also selects a House Majority leader; the minority party selects a Senate Minority Leader and a House Minority; both parties in both chambers also select “party whips” (individuals whose main responsibility is to help party leaders maintain the votes of their own members.) The jobs of legislative leaders in the U.S. Congress is usually much more complicated than that of their parliamentary counterparts. Parties exist to promote cooperation, but the Speaker of the House and the Majority leader of the Senate have no real way to discipline recalcitrant legislators; successful leaders in the American Congress have to be expert bargainers and deal-makers, in order to forge compromise within their own parties and, often enough, with opposing parties or opposing Presidents. In comparison with parliamentary leaders, Congressional party leaders have few tools to discipline their members. The limits of party discipline in Congress, and the limited power of Congressional leaders, is actually the source of Congressional power; party discipline in parliamentary regimes insures that Prime Ministers, cabinet, and the bureaucracy dominate the policy making process.

Party leaders in the U.S. House and Senate includes play a key role in making initial committee assignments (see below) and in setting the legislative agenda. The committee assignment power has changed in significant ways over the years, but the main concern of party leaders is to insure that they have solid majorities on the major committees. A secondary, but still important, concerns is to assign individual legislators to committees where they will be able to make the most significant contribution. This usually means assigning people to committees that are of particular concern to their constituents. Setting the legislative agenda is not something that Congress controls entirely; in a formal sense, however, the leaders of the House and Senate bear responsibility for assigning bills to committees, establishing the legislative calendar (the schedule which establishes which bills will be taken up before the full House and Senate), and, in general, overseeing the law-making process.

In addition to party leaders, Congress is also organized into caucuses– groups, some of which are bi-partisan, which are united based upon shared ideology, shared interests, or shared identity. For instance, the Congressional Black Caucus consists of African American legislators, and has included members from both parties. Other congressional caucuses are organized around ideology– such as the conservative Republican Study Committee, or the Blue Dog Coalition, a caucus which consists of moderate Democrats from conservative leaning regions of the country. While not as crucial as party leaders, caucus organizations can play a role in helping to identify public problems, advance policy ideas, and alert party leaders to the concerns of the party rank and file.

c) Congressional Committees

Many aspects of Congress are established by the Constitutionalism; bi-cameralism and the Presidential veto are two examples of institutional features established by the Constitution that shape the and cannot be easily changed. legislative process. Yet the internal operation of Congress is not determined by the Constitution, at least not directly. The organization of parties, and the process of analyzing and reviewing legislative proposals, are not determined by the Constitution itself. The Constitution sets certain rules in place– for instance, the rule that a bill only becomes a law when it is passed in identical form by the House and Senate. Yet Congress itself determines the structure of the legislative process. The most important institutional feature of this process is the committee system.

Committees are sub-groups within Congress that review and develop legislative proposals. Their primary role in the legislative process is to act as gate-keepers of the legislative process– that is, they decide which proposals will be taken seriously, and which will be thrown under the bus. The basic purpose of congressional committees35 is to prepare bills for consideration in the House and the Senate, something which could not be accomplished without the division of labour. In order to prepare bills for consideration and voting in the House and Senate, committees hold “hearings”36 and “mark-up” bills to craft the specific language used in the bill.. Committees also play an important “gatekeeping” function—they determine what kinds of issues will receive serious attention, and they determine which issues can be ignored (though we should note that committee gatekeepers have to be attentive to the wishes of party leaders and the President.)

Table 5.3: House Committees
Committee Name Jurisdiction (examples)a
Agriculture Agriculture (including farm credit, commodity exchanges, rural development), SNAP (Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program)
Appropriations Expenditure bills
Budget
Education and the Workforce
Energy and Commerce
Ethics
Financial Services
Foreign Affairs
Homeland Security
Intelligence
Judiciary
Natural Resources
Oversight and Government Reform
Rules
Science, Space and Technology
Small Business
Transportation and Infrastructure
Veterans Affairs
Ways and Means

There are several committees which are particularly noteworthy. The House Rules Committee determines the parameters of debate within the House; while the Rules Committee was once a major thorn in the side of Congressional majorities37, since the 1960s it has been carefully controlled by party leaders.38 The House Appropriations Committee has jurisdiction over annual appropriation bills—that is, bills that deal with discretionary government spending, as opposed to “entitlement” spending such as Social Security; this committee is responsible for reviewing and considering the budget requests of the President and executive branch agencies, and is thus particularly important.39 The House Committee on Ways and Means has jurisdiction over tax bills, as well as social programs such as Social Security and Medicare.40 The House Budget Committee exists to oversee the budget reconciliation process.41

One of the most important dynamics in Congress is the relative balance of power between committees and parties, particularly party leaders. Committees are not necessarily representative of Congress in an ideological sense, though the balance of votes on committees reflects the official partisan balance of power. Congress as a whole delegates power and responsibility to committees, but it is possible for the interests of the committee to diverge from the interests of Congress as a whole.

There are three basic theories about the role of committees– all of which are true to some extent, though not at the same time and in the same way. The “Committee Autonomy- Distributional Hypothesis” is that committees control outcomes relevant to their constituencies, jurisdiction, and policy interests; in practice, this makes committee politics the locus of institutionalized log-rolling and parochialism. In other words, the decisions made by committees might not reflect the decisions that majorities in the House and Senate would make, if there was no “division of labour” in the legislative process and all members of the House and Senate were able to decide upon all issues. One example of this “principal-agent”42 problem is the House Agriculture Committee and its relationship to the Republican Party. The Republican Party is, in theory, a “neo-liberal” party which opposes government subsidies for business; the members who sit on the House Agricultural committee, however, are motivated not merely by ideology but also by their interest in being re-elected by their rural constituents. Regardless of the neo-liberal ideology of the party as a whole, the Republican members of the House Agricultural committee are usually reluctant to give up on ethanol subsidies, sugar subsidies, and other policies that direct federal money to struggling agri-business conglomerates.43

But committee members are not always captured by the interests that they represent. According to the informational hypothesis, the committees allow members of Congress to divide their labour and develop specialized expertise; according to the “party dominance” theory, committees are organized to advance the interests of the majority party, and thus the votes and decisions of committee members usually reflect what party majorities prefer, and not just the short term interests of the committee’s constituents. As we will see, however, committees have various tools that allow them to frustrate the will of the majority—though these tools become less significant during periods when the parties are united by shared beliefs or ideologies.

The role of committees is a good example of a “centrifugal forces” in American Congressional politics. Committees can limit the power of “the center” (in this case, party leaders in Congress, backed by partisan majorities) , in contrast with parliamentary politics, where power lies at the centre, in the cabinet and the Prime Minister. To understand Congress, we must understand the following things: bi-cameralism and the institutional differences between the House and Senate; the potential tensions between Congressional majorities and committees; the inter-relationship between Parties, Party Leaders, and Individual legislators; and the relationship between Congress and the Presidency in the legislative process. Encompassing all of these relationships is the interaction between public opinion and the legislative process, a relationship which is much more dynamic in the American system as opposed to parliamentary systems. The American legislative process, under contemporary conditions, has a tendency to spill over into the public arena. We must understand the interests and ideas that motivate legislators, and the institutions that structure how they pursue their interests and implement their ideas.

V. The Legislative Process

a) Agenda Setting

Now that we have considered the basic institutional structure of the legislative process, we can consider what the process looks like in practice. The first stage in the legislative process is the “proposal” or “agenda setting” stage, leading to the “introduction” of a bill. While a member of the House has to formally introduce a bill, there are no specific rules about where policy proposals can come from.44 There are standard norms for determining what proposals will be taken seriously, however. At any given moment in time, there are an almost inexhaustible number of possible policy issues that Congress might choose to address; to set the agenda, then, is simply to set priorities, to make decisions about what issues will be the focus of Congressional action, and what issues will be ignored. Almost always, the President’s proposals will be the primary influence one the Congressional agenda. In addition, party organizations within Congress– the Republican Conference and the Democratic Caucus– will be the source of legislative proposals; one example of this is Newt Gingrich’s “Contract with America,” from 1994. Yet agenda-setting cannot be understood if we only look at actors within the national government.

Agenda-setting in Congress occurs through a combination of disparate social forces and individual action. In some instances, the agenda is set by literally decades of “ideological entrepreneurship”: a process of identifying policy problems, articulating possible solutions, and disseminating those ideas through the broader public sphere.45 The proposals and platforms of Presidents and political parties are thus only the tip of the agenda-setting iceberg. Mass media can play a role in setting the policy agenda by drawing attention to certain kinds of problems, or framing problems in particular ways. Policy entrepreneurs– individuals, interest groups, or even broader social movements– can play a similar role in identifying public policy problems and suggesting policy solutions. Finally crises of various kinds, whether natural, economic, or political, can re-shape the Congressional agenda in unexpected ways.

Mass media, policy entrepreneurs, and crises often work together simultaneously in setting the Congressional legislative agenda. Consider, for in the instance, the response of Congress to the financial crisis of 2008. Much like the Great Depression of the 1930s, the causes of the financial crisis are numerous, complicated, and poorly understood, at least in the sense that highly qualified economic policy experts have come to differing conclusions over the precise causes of the financial crisis. Mass media played a role in shaping public consciousness of the causes of the financial crisis by highlighting a fairly simple and straightforward narrative about the causes of the crisis: the crisis was caused by excessive speculation by financial institutions, and further crises can be prevented by subjecting financial institutions to stricter regulation.46 While the public may have been more amenable to the idea of strict financial regulation after experiencing the effects of the financial crisis and media interpretations of the crisis, this does not mean that “the public” has any particular ideas about what stricter regulation might mean in practice. This is where policy entrepreneurs play a role, in this case, by developing specific ideas about how to frame legislation. For instance, prior to becoming Senator, Elizabeth Warren had developed the idea that financial products should be subjected to government evaluation and regulation, similar to the ways in which new pharmaceuticals are evaluated by the Food and Drug Administration. Warren’s ideas became basis for the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, one of the most significant and most controversial elements of the Dodd-Frank financial reforms. 47

Legislative proposals typically originate in three different ways: from the Presidency and the Executive, from Congressional party leadership, and from individual legislative entrepreneurs within Congress. The Dodd-Frank Act of 2010 is a good example of a legislative proposal that began within the executive branch. President Obama had raised the issue of financial reform during his Presidential primary campaign, well-before the financial crisis had occurred. In the aftermath of the financial crash, Obama administration officials, along with a variety of academic experts, laid the groundwork for the initial legislative proposal that would become the Dodd-Frank bill.48 In other circumstances, the legislative agenda is set by the majority party, as in the aftermath of the 1994 election when the Newt Gingrich-led Congressional Republicans attempted to implement their “Contract with America.”49 Individual legislators also play a key role in establishing the legislative agenda. Whether as a consequence of their own individual policy ideas, or as a consequence of their relationship with influential interest groups, individual legislators in the American Congress often play a crucial role in developing policy ideas and pushing political issues onto the Congressional agenda.50 One should also note that Presidents, the executive branch, Congressional leaders, and individual legislative entrepreneurs often work together simultaneously to establish a legislative agenda.

Looked at more broadly, setting the legislative agenda is a process that encompasses both government officials as well as interest groups and public opinion. Part of the great difficulty of understanding this process is that “agenda-setting” encompasses both issues that draw Congress’ attention, but also issues that fail to draw Congress– what might be called “negative agenda setting.” While there are many different ways of looking at the agenda setting process, James Q. Wilson’s theory of policy-making, based upon the ways in which different policies impose costs and benefits is a useful starting point. According to Wilson, Congressional policies impose costs that are concentrated on particular set of individuals or groups, or they impose costs that are diffused through society as a whole. Benefits are distributed in a similar way. This yields four theoretically distinct types of policy areas, each of which creates a distinct kind of politics; they are presented in the “Wilson grid” below:

Table 5.4: The Wilson Grid: Public Policy and the Distribution of Costs and Benefits
BenefitsCosts Concentrated Widely Distributed
Concentrated Interest Group Politics Client Politics
Widely Distributed Entrepreneurial Politics Majoritarian Politics

Interest Group Politics: This form of politics tends to occur when the benefits and costs of a policy fall upon (relatively) small sectors of society. The usual (and most important) example of this category of policy-making are laws that affect labor rights and labor organization; the agenda in this area of policy-making will be set by the relative power of union and business organizations (which will depend upon the strength of their supporters and allies within Congress.)

Majoritarian Politics: Majoritarian policies impose costs and distribute benefits to society as a whole (or to large swathes of society.) The most important example of this type of policy-making is income tax policy, though as we will see tax policy can also take the form of “client politics.”

Client Politics: Client politics occurs when the benefits of a policy affect a relatively concentrated group, while the cost are imposed on society as a whole. The best example of this kind of policy-making are policies that direct subsidies to particular groups e.g. farmers, weapons manufacturers, etc.

Entrepreneurial Politics: Some of the most contentious forms of policy-making in Congress occurs when legislators attempt to create laws that provide public benefits while imposing costs on relatively concentrated (and thus, easier to organize) constituencies. Safety regulation, drug regulation, and environmental regulation all fall into this category. This type of policy-making is called “entrepreneurial” because overcoming the resistance of entrenched interests usually requires the leadership of “policy entrepreneurs” insides and outside of Congress: highly motivated and skilled individuals who are able to promote policy ideas even in the face of interest group resistance.

Banking and finance reform during the Obama administration illustrate some of the problems and difficulties “entrepreneurial politics” in Congress; it also shows how the same policy domain can, depending upon what Congress is trying to do, fall into different categories. The public, arguably, has an interest in a stable financial system, one in which public money is not spent to save private investment banks and insurers; those same financial institutions want to benefit from limited regulation during good times, and they want governments to provide support for them during financial crises. Imposing major regulations on the financial industry usually requires a precipitating event or series of events, such as the Great Depression of the 1930s or the financial crisis of 2008. In the aftermath of those events, policy entrepreneurs within Congress were able to overcome, at least in part, the power of the “financial-industrial complex” to stymie reform. At the very least, supporters of financial reform (such as Massachusetts politicians Barney Frank and Elizabeth Warren) were able to get the issue on the Congressional agenda.

b)The Legislative Process in the House and Senate: Committees

Once the agenda is established, party leaders in the House and Senate start sending the work out to relevant committees; this is the “referral” process. The role of the Speaker of the House is very significant here; they monitor and guide what is happening within the committees, in order to help insure that the legislation will be acceptable to their party as a whole. Leadership in the House becomes even more significant when you are dealing with large, complex bills– sometimes called “omnibus” bills– that do not even deal with related issues; in regards to these bills, the Speaker plays the role of coordinator between committees. The ultimate goal at the committee stage is to create legislation that will be acceptable to most party members, pass the House, and not undermine the party’s electoral fortunes. This is not always easy.

Parties in the legislature do not necessarily have to rely on committees in order to develop legislative proposals. Between the 1960s and the 1980s, 7% of major pieces of legislation “bypassed” the committee process in the Senate; between 2009 and 2014, an average of 52% of major legislative proposals were not considered in committees.51 This is probably a sign of the increased ideological homogeneity in Congress. In the past, members of Congress were more jealous about the prerogatives of the committees, because they assumed—often correctly—that the perspectives of committee members might well differ from the perspective of their parties as a whole. In the first systematic study of committee politics, conducted in the 1960s, the political scientist Richard Fenno emphasized that congressional committees were to some degree independent of their political parties; the interests of individual members of Congress (in getting re-elected, in achieving personal influence and power, and creating good public policy) were often served by maintaining committee autonomy (the ability of committees to dominate the law-making process.) Yet as political parties have become more polarized, and as electoral outcomes have become more uncertain, partisan identity has become more significant than committee membership; under these circumstances, it is more common for individual members to accept a reduced role for committees, at least under some circumstances.

The House has the ability to bring committee deliberation (or committee stalling) to an end by using a discharge petition, which require signatures from a majority in the House and can be proposed by any member. Discharge petitions attempt to end the committee stage of the legislative process, particularly if the committee is hostile or ambivalent. They are, however, relatively rare: between 1931 and 2010 there were 628 discharge petitions, and only 31 of these petitions actually led to a discharge (this is probably because the threat of discharge is effective in getting committees to get their act together.)52

There are many reasons why leaders and members might want to pressure committees, or might want to bypass them altogether. In some cases, time pressure makes it necessary to move to consideration on the floor as quickly as possible; this was the case regarding TARP legislation in the fall of 2008. In other cases, the legislation may have already been considered in previous sessions of Congress, or the majority may want to pass a law very quickly without attracting public attention.

Party leaders often have to play a role in reconciling complex bills that have been parcelled out to multiple committees—this is the “post-committee adjustment” stage which precedes consideration on the floor. In addition to addressing discrepancies between bills that have been referred to multiple committees, party leaders may wish to change parts of the bill in order to increase support, whether from members of Congress or the President.

Within political science, there are two main theories which attempt to explain how committees conduct their work. According to the “Informational Model,” —committees simply allow members of Congress to specialize, thereby reducing uncertainty and improving the quality of legislative output. By way of contrast, the “gains from trade” model suggests that committees consist of “preference outliers” who pursue policies that depart from the preferences of the majority. Committees engage in a collective “logrolling” process, in which the special deals of one committee are accepted by other members, who have their own special deals and arrangements that they hope will sustained by the legislature. Both theories are partially true.53 Looking at the committee process allows us to understand how, even in an era of partisan polarization, the legislative process requires Congressional leaders to balance the interests of competing “factions,” at least within the committee process.

The “informational model” of Congress suggests that the main purpose of congressional committees is to allow individual members to develop relevant expertise. One of the troubling themes that emerges in detailed investigations of law-making, such as An Act of Congress by Robert Kaiser, is that congressional committees are, in practice, composed of individuals with very limited expertise. Even those who have been longstanding members of standing committees have very imperfect understandings of key policy issues. The usual complaint of representatives and Senators is that the demands of constituency service and fundraising make it difficult for them to acquire knowledge. More troubling is the possibility that no amount of time and effort would enable legislators to fully understand all of the complexities of issues such as financial regulation and health care politics.

Robert Kaiser’s narrative about the passage of the Dodd-Frank bill in 2009-2010 suggests that there was no real “informational advantage” amongst members of the committee as a whole. In practice, only a relatively small group of legislators and Congressional aides have enough expertise to really understand the relevant policy issues. Even though members of Congress played a role in developing the bill, much of the substance of the bill has already been developed by officials from the executive branch (in the case of the Dodd-Frank bill, the executive branch officials were mostly from the Treasury department). In many cases, the substance of the legislation was developed by individuals with unusually close connections to the financial industry itself. Deference to executive branch officials is more prominent in committee work, as opposed to rabid partisan squabbling. There is thus a kind of convergence between the parliamentary-executive dominated model of law-making, and the American Congressional model, especially when we are dealing with highly complex pieces of legislation. This raises all kinds of interesting questions: are (unaccountable officials) acting on the basis of expertise, or on the basis of their interests? To what extent are aides/experts influenced by connections to the world of high finance? Though it is only one example, the role played by the House Financial Services Committee in creating the Dodd-Frank financial regulations suggest some of the limits of the “informational model.” There are clearly individual representatives who develop significant policy-making expertise, but they may be an exception, not the norm. 54

What about the “gains from trade” model? To what extent do the individual interests of members of the committee shape the legislative product? In general, the picture that Robert Kaiser paints in An Act of Congress is not pretty. For much of the “mark up” sessions, most committee members are absent, which in practice means they are willing to defer to decisions about the bill that have already been made by the drafters from Treasury Department, as well as by the decisions of committee staff members and Chair Barney Frank. “Preference Outliers” do play a role, as we can see in the case of the “auto dealer’s carve out.” The issue in this case was the jurisdiction of the new Consumer Financial Protection Agency (CFPA, eventually named the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau), which was going to be empowered to regulate financial products. The auto-carve out was a successful amendment offered by John Campbell (R-CA) which exempted auto dealers from the jurisdiction of the CFPA (auto dealers offer financial products in the form of loans., and they would have otherwise been subject to the jurisdiction of the CFPA.) The auto-industry had given Campbell close to $200,000 in campaign contributions, and he made considerable sums from his own auto-dealer related properties.55 We should note that it isn’t clear whether this caused the law to depart from from the preferences of members of the House as a whole. Committee chair Barney Frank accepted the amendment because he did not want to needlessly antagonize auto dealers. This example might show that committees are venues for interest group influence, but it is hard to prove that the “carve out” was a consequence of preference outliers on the committee

Other aspects of the Dodd Frank saga also illustrate how difficult it can be to determine whether commitee decisions are the result of the idiosyncratic ideologies of representatives, the influence of constituents and interest groups, or part of a genuine attempt to create public policy that serves the public good. Consider the example of federal pre-emption, an important issue in the debate over the Dodd-Frank financial regulations .The basic question raised by federal pre-emption is this: if the federal government can regulate various aspects of banks and financial markets, can states continue to regulate them as well? For Barney Frank and may progressive Democrats, the answer to this question was “yes;” the law should only establish a federal “floor,” and not prevent states from making their own additions to the regulatory structure.56 Themoderate Democrats (sometimes referred to as “New Democrats”) on the House financial services committee had different views—they wanted additional protections for the banks, and they had the numbers to make their voices heard: “New Democrats” on the committee constituted the single largest Democratic “faction,” holding 16 out of 42 democratic seats.

This issue was resolved through statutory ambiguity. The original language of the bill that dealt with pre-emption stated that state regulators cannot do anything that “prevents or significantly interferes with” the operation of national banks. The final language of the bill, revised to please New Democrats, stated that “state regulators cannot do anything that ‘prevents or significantly interferes with or materially impairs’ the operation of national banks.” What this would mean in practice was anyone’s guess, but the New Democrats could at least claim to have given something to the financial community. Lawyers, courts, and money would resolve the issue, not legislators.

The horse trading that occurred as part of the development of the Dodd-Frank financial reforms can illuminate some aspects of the both the “Informational” and “Gains from Trade” model of congressional committees. The case suggests that the informational model is rather limited, though this may be a consequence of the complexity of financial regulation as a subject matter. Yet we should also keep in mind that some of the committee members, Barney Frank most importantly, had in fact developed relevant expertise over the course of their careers. Some members have an informational advantage, though not all.57 Similarly, the “gains from trade” or “preference outlier” model does not really explain what occurred in the House Financial Services committee; the factional politics on display within the committee (featuring centrist Democrats versus New Left Democrats) reflects the overall divisions within the Democratic Party. The problem revealed by Dodd-Frank is rather different: extreme complexity makes it difficult for legislators to know what they are doing. The law was developed by executive branch bureaucrats and congressional aides, who are quick to wander through the revolving door to the financial industry. In regards to one of the most important pieces of legislation passed in the last 10 years, neither the informational model nor the “gains from trade-preference outlier” model works very well.

Political issues depend upon attention and complexity. This has been particularly prominent in regards to issues in financial reform in the Obama administration– the people involved in government financial regulation are so closely tied to Wall Street that their “world view” is ultimately distorted (we need not even bring in the question of whether outright corruption is involved.) Most people regard the financial reforms undertaken by the Obama administration as fairly watered down; plans to create an FDA-like bureaucracy that would pre-approve new financial products were reduced an even eliminated, for instance. To some extent, the “expert advice” about financial regulation– from officials in the Federal Reserve, the U.S. Department of the Treasury– will constrain what Presidents and Congress regard as feasible. The sphere of financial regulation and banking in the United States is shaped not only by Congress and the President, but by the cadres of officials and bureaucrats (in both parties) who move between the world of government and high finance. There are few Presidents, and few members of Congress, who are able to challenge “policy networks” of this kind, and it doesn’t require any kind of conspiracy to see why– politicians are, for the most part, experts in getting elected, and while they are surely not ignorant about finance in comparison with the general public, their ability to challenge the expertise of finance professionals is invariably limited.

Bringing a bill “to the floor” refers to the process through which a bill moves from the committee stage to consideration by the House and Senate as a whole. The House brings bills to the floor through “rules” crafted by the Rules Committee, and the Senate uses “unanimous consent agreements.” The “rules” of the House usually give an advantage to the majority party, whereas unanimous consent agreements aim to accommodate the interests of the minority party (as much as possible) and even individual members (as we will see, this result from the ability of any Senator to use a filibuster to delay proceedings in the Senate.) In the House, most major bills are brought to the floor under special rules which allocate time for debate and determine what kinds of amendments can be offered. An open rule, by way of contrast, allows for all germane amendments. There are two major categories of special rules. Closed rules prohibit all amendments other than those specified by the committee. Under structured rules, some but not all germane amendments can be offered. Closed and structured rules prevent the minority party from adding amendments, which might lead the majority party to split apart or fragment, thus making the bill impossible to pass as a whole. Sometimes, leaders want to prevent anyone from adding elements to the bill that would command majority support (though not the support of party leaders.) Restrictive rules also allow parties to package together things that their members like with things that they don’t like, and then forcing the members to vote on the whole thing. This allows Congress to make some difficult decisions, but still allows members to avoid taking full responsibility for all aspects of their votes. Between 1993 and 2008, 78% of major bills operated under closed or structured rules; between 2010 and 2012, on the other hand, no legislation was brought under a simple open rule

If the Rule is approved, the House resolves itself into Committee of the Whole. Under the Committee of the Whole, the House is not formally in session; it conducts a kind of preliminary debate, with a smaller quorum, and with streamlined rules of debate. The floor managers of the bill state why the bill is perfect and wonderful, and allot time for debate; any amendments that are approved by the Committee of the Whole must still be voted on by the House in a formal session.

To understand the legislative process in the House, you need to understand that the majority party uses “the rules” (that structure debate time and particularly the amendment process) in order to preserve its majorities. In practice, this means that party leaders prevent votes on amendments that might pass (unless they support the amendment.) Consider the following example. The Federal Housing and Finance Reform Act of 2005 was reported out of committee by a vote of 65-5; in other words, there was a strong bi-partisan consensus in favour of the bill. However, the bill contained provisions for an affordable housing fund, which was opposed by many House GOP members. The Rules Committee amended the bill and prohibited the Democrats from amending the amendment, thereby eliminating the provisions that were objectionable to a majority of Republicans.

The committee stage in the Senate has several important differences with the House. First, and most obviously, the senate is much smaller– 100 Senators must do the same work as 435 representatives. On the other hand, every Senator is likely to either be a committee chair or sub-committee chair. The most important difference between the House and the Senate, however, lies in the way in which bills move from committee to votes on “the floor” of the chambers as a whole.

In the House of Representatives, procedures for voting tend to be partisan and majoritarian. The legislative process in the Senate tends to be much more complicated, for the simple reason that an individual Senator can cause more trouble in the legislative process. At the most basic level, having one vote out of 100 gives you more influence than having one vote out of 435. More significant is the way in which Senators can obstruct the legislative process through the filibuster. The House structures the time of debate through the rules created by the Rules Committee; the Senate has a tradition of more open ended debate on the floor– though it is certainly not unlimited. The equivalent to the House “Rule” in the Senate is a unanimous consent agreement— basically, an agreement to set certain limits on debate and amendments, in order to proceed to an up or down vote. The Senate majority and minority leaders determine whether or not any of their members wish to place a “hold” on a bill– a hold is essentially a threat to engage in a filibuster, that is, an extended speech that is undertaken to prevent vote on a particular measure. Thus unanimous consent agreements really are unanimous; every last Senator agrees on the terms of the debate. Filibusters can be stopped through a “cloture vote,” a vote of 60+ members who agree to bring debate to an end. But the essential idea here is that a minority of senators, even a determined individual, can cause a great deal of havoc in the legislative process, mostly through their power to delay the proceedings.

c) Reconciling the House and the Senate

Before a bill can proceed to the President’s desk, the House and the Senate must pass identical bills. Conference committees, composed of both Senators and Representatives, were for many years the most important device used to reconcile differences between House and Senate bills. Conference committees are usually composed of members of the House and Senate committees who played critical roles in developing a bill. If the conference committee is able to reach a compromise, then this version of the bill must be voted on again in both chambers. In regards to minor pieces of legislation, or legislation where the differences are small, one chamber might be willing to accept the other’s bill. For example, in 2009 the House accepted the Senate’s version of a bill which extend the State Children’s Health Insurance Program; in late 2004, the House agreed to a Senate bill which placed a moratorium on internet taxes

Amendments between the chambers, sometimes called ping-ponging, are now used frequently to reconcile bills in the House and Senate. In fact, this method appears to be replacing conference committees as the major mechanism for reconciliation: Between the 1960s-1990s 76% of major measures went to conference committees; in 2000, 47% of major measures went to conference committee; in the year 2009-2010, only 22% of major measures went to conference committee. The reason for this change is relatively simple: members of the majority party are more confident in their leadership, due to the increased ideological homogeneity within their part, and as a result, committee members are less likely to demand that they play a role in the reconciling conflicting bills.

d) Understanding the Legislative Process: Pivotal Legislators

So what is the best way to understand this complicated process? The nominal control of the House and Senate by one party will not tell us very much, because parties can be internally divided, and party leaders often are unable to discipline and constrain party members. Thus, one way to understand what actually happens in Congress is to focus on pivotal legislators—those legislators who, in ideological terms, stand in the middle of the ideological spectrum, legislators whose votes are necessary to reach majorities in either the House or Senate.58 Policy change or policy maintenance in Congress depends upon the choices and preferences of legislators who cluster in the middle of the political spectrum–the legislators who are most likely to depart from their party–and thus the legislators who possess the “pivotal” votes that determine whether legislation will succeed or fail. Thus, even in circumstances of “divided party control” of government, there can be considerable legislative activity.

Consider the Reagan Era, where every piece of law on Reagan’s agenda had to be passed by a “Democratic” House of Representatives– the pivotal legislators in the Democratic Party, those clustered around the middle or even the right of the ideological spectrum, were willing to join the GOP on many crucial votes, particularly in areas such as tax reform.59 Parties are weak and majorities are evanescent; as a result, to understand the legislative process you must consider the legislators who are most likely to play a pivotal role in the outcomes

Even in an era of ideological polarization, an era when partisans are supposedly more unified than in the past, there are examples that can illustrate the weakness of parties and party leaders in the legislative process. Even on questions where the ideological stakes divide the parties, a relatively small number of defectors can make the legislative process an uncertain and complicated process. Consider, first, the example of “cap and trade” legislation during the Obama administration.60 Environmental policy had long been a priority of the Democratic party, and many were confident that, after the 2008 election which gave the Democrats control of the House, Senate, and the Presidency, the party would be able implement significant climate change measures. Yet while the the cap and trade legislation was passed in the House, it failed in the Senate; in fact, it was not even brought to a vote on the Senate floor. Part of the problem was that, while the Democrats had a majority in the Senate, with only 59 members, they did not have a “filibuster-proof” majority (60 votes are required to end a filibuster in the Senate, which basically means that 60 votes are required to bring debate to a conclusion and force a vote on the bill.) Yet it was also the case that the Democrats could not be certain of receiving support from all Democratic Senators; Senators from oil and coal producing states, or states that were dependent upon oil and coal for energy, had no intention of supporting cap and trade. The differing geographic interests of members of Congress can be seen in the House vote, in which 44 Democrats (almost 20% of the House Democratic caucus) voted against the bill– with most of them coming from states that would have been adversely affected by the policy, at least in economic terms.

Figure 5.4: Districts of House Democrats who voted against Cap and Trade (American Clean Energy and Security Act, 2009)

A more recent example of the limits of party discipline in the Congressional law-making process is the failed attempt of the Republican Party to repeal Obamacare in 2017. While the House GOP passed repeal legislation, Republicans in the Senate were unable to maintain their unanimity: John McCain of Arizona, Liza Murkowski of Alaska, and Susan Collins of Maine all voted against their fellow Republican Senators. In a year, and a time, when so much had seemed abnormal, this was very much business as usual for Congress. Individual members of Congress are supposed to consult their own consciences, and the interests of their own constituents, when voting on questions of public importance. Thus while partisan ideological polarization often makes it seem as if individual idiosyncrasies and regional differences are no longer significant as they once were, these “centrifugal forces” continue to play a crucial role in Congressional politics. When majorities are small, almost every vote matters; in the American Congress, not every vote is determined by party affiliation.

VI. The Historical Development of Congress in the 20th and 21st Century: From the “Textbook Congress” to the “Hyper-Partisan Congress.”

The legislative process—the relationship between parties, committees, individual legislators, and the President—has changed in significant ways over the course of American history. The differences between the “textbook system” in Congress, which operated from roughly the 1910s to the 1970s, and the contemporary or “post-reform” era in Congress, are useful to consider, as the contemporary Congress is usually regarded as dysfunctional, and the mid-twentieth century Congress is usually held out as a model of “how things are supposed to work.” You might say that history will teach us nothing, we only need to know about what is happening in Congress now. That would be both unscientific and unwise; unscientific, because we need some points of comparison in order to appreciate the significance of Congressional institutions, unwise, because contemporary criticisms of Congress are based on the notion that the so-called “textbook” system is the proper way for Congress to operate. This may be true, but this means we should pay some attention to the characteristics of the “golden age” of Congress, an era where partisan divisions were not as extreme, when the work in committees and on the floor was more consensual, where Senators used the filibuster infrequently, and unusual legislative procedures were relatively uncommon as well.

In terms of its institutional structure, the “textbook Congress” was based upon the seniority system for Congressional committee assignments and leadership positions within committees. In terms of the operation of Congress, much of the textbook era was characterized by Presidential leadership in the legislative arena (combined with considerable, though far from unlimited, autonomy for committee chairs) , specialization by individual members of Congress in a select number of policy fields, and an increased focus by Senators and Representatives on constituency service, government oversight, and pork barrel spending. In terms of the political and electoral context, the textbook era was characterized by the “incumbency advantage,” long term Democratic control within Congress, and considerable ideological overlap between the parties.

There are continuities between the textbook era and the contemporary era—incumbents still tend to get re-elected, members of Congress still tend to specialize, and Presidents continue to play a leading role in setting the legislative agenda. Yet in the 21st century, Congress and the committee system operate in very different political circumstances—the power of party leaders has increased while committee autonomy has decreased, and consensual decision making has been abandoned in favour of hyper-partisan legislative strategies. Congressional leaders possess the capacity to challenge Presidents for leadership of the political agenda. Neither the “textbook system” or the contemporary “hyper-partisan” system is normal or natural—both the textbook system and the hyper-partisan system of today are possible outcomes of the institutional structure of American government. If Congress appears to be broken, it is because the political order as a whole has produced politicians who are less inclined to co-operate and compromise. Conflict and gridlock within Congress are not a sign that the system is “broken”; conflict and gridlock are possibilities created by the Constitutional order.

The Birth of the “Textbook Congress”: From Party Government to Committee Government

We will begin by considering the transition from “Party Government” to “Committee Government” which occurred around the beginning of the 20th century. “Party government” refers to a system of Congressional organization in which party leaders (such as the Speaker of the House) were relatively powerful, in terms of their ability to manage the legislative process and influence recalcitrant members of their own parties. “Committee government” was based upon a shift in relative power from party leaders to committees and committee chairs. This shift was connected with the increased influence of “Progressivism” in American politics; just as importantly, Presidents increased their ability to influence the legislative process, as well as their ability to directly shape policy through control of executive branch bureaucracies. The era of the “textbook Congress” was thus also the era of “the imperial Presidency.”

In order to understand this process, let us consider a few general features about Congress as it had developed up until the beginning of the 20th century. The first thing to note about the operation of Congress at the beginning of the 20th century is that it was organized to empower party leaders, particularly the Speaker of the House (the leader of the majority party in the House of Representatives.) Party leaders influenced members– that is, they tried to compel them to adhere to the party’s positions on policy issues– in the following ways. First, party leaders controlled committee assignments, and thus could punish recalcitrant party members by giving them uninteresting or unimportant committee assignments. Secondly, parties were crucial in elections (or in the case of Senators, selection by state legislatures.) Parties controlled the nominating process, and it was more difficult for individuals to win elections based upon their own fund-raising and individual or “candidate-centered” organizations. Furthermore, throughout much of the nineteenth century, congressional elections tended to be highly competitive; individual members of Congress required the support of their parties to win elections, and parties at the state and local level tended to prize party loyalty. It is true that the patterns of electoral competition changed after the Civil War, as party competition was less significant in the south– much less significant. But, in general, the role of parties in elections, and the power of party leaders in Congress, imposed a considerable amount of party discipline within Congress.

The transition to the “textbook” system of Congress started at the end of the 19th century, though 1910 was the critical turning point. Members of both parties in the House took steps to limit the power of the Speaker of the House; for instance, by eliminating the power of the Speaker to select (and thus control) the all important Rules Committee, the committee responsible for determining the contours of debate in the House (such as the time allotted to debate, whether amendments will be allowed, and so forth.)

Figure 5.5: Vote on House Resolution 502 (March 19th,1910) (Creates a 10 member House Rules Committee, elected by the House; Speaker of the House excluded from the Committee

Dark Red GOP “Yea”
Peach GOP “Nay”
Blue Democrat “Yea”
White Absent 61

The ability of autocratic party leaders to discipline individual members through control of committee assignments was brought to an end during this period. This was probably the most important consequence of the bi-partisan revolt against Speaker of the House Joe “Uncle Joe” Cannon in 1910. Congress adopted the “seniority system” in committee assignments, which meant that, once appointed to a committee, a member retained that assignment until they lost their seat. Committee chairs were determined by the seniority system as well, and in addition, the Speaker of the House lost the ability to control the Rules Committee in the House. Recall that the purpose of the Rules Committee is to structure and control the legislative process in the House of Representatives; the Rules Committee in the House structures debate on the floor of the House, in particular by determining the timing of debate, and the possibility for offering amendments.

Why did these changes occur? The causes of the revolt against Party leadership relate to broader changes in the electorate, and broader changes in the parties, but, in essence, the changes occurred because the parties were becoming more internally divided along ideological lines. The Republicans and the Democrats each has “progressive” and “conservative” wings. Now, this raises an obvious question: why didn’t conservatives gravitate to one party, and progressives to the other? The answer is that the parties had become more “regionalized,” with the GOP strong in the North and the Mid-West, the Democrats strong in the south. General elections were not as competitive as they once had been, and thus ideological battles often occurred within parties. This was aided by the growing significance of primary elections for the selection of candidates, and, of course, the adoption of the 17th amendment which required direct election for Senators. The ideological differences within the parties created a critical mass of politicians who wanted to limit the power of parties as a whole, as they could no longer be certain that members of the same political party shared the same political priorities. Progressives wanted to reduce the power of party leaders in Congress, because they thought that conservative party leaders (whether Democrats or Republicans) were obstructing the progressive legislative agenda. The irony here is that committee government, particularly by the 1960s, would be regarded by progressives as the central obstacle to the continued development of progressivism.

b) Committee Government and the Modern Administrative State, 1910-1960s

The era of committee government coincided, more or less, with the expansion of federal responsibilities and the power of the executive branch—in other words, committee government grew up alongside the modern administrative state. The most important features of Congress during this period were as follows: increased power for committee chairs, increased specialization on the part of individual representatives, and the changed relationship between Congress and the President.

Committee government was based upon the seniority system (the power of individual Senators and representatives to maintain their positions on committees, regardless of the wishes of the party) along with the ability of elected officials to maintain their own electoral power base (due to both the primary system and candidate-centered campaigning.) How did Congress operate under this new system? First, let us consider the power of committee chairs, who were now protected by the seniority system.During this era, committee chairs were often described as “barons,” and I think that this is largely because of their independent power to shape the development of “bills.”

Committee Chairs exercised authority in many different forms:

i) gatekeeping authority: Committee chairs had the power to determine which bills would actually be developed through hearings62 and mark-ups63. During the era of committee government, party leaders had very little ability to challenge decisions made by committee chairs; if a chair made a decision to obstruct the development of a bill, then it was almost impossible for party leaders to intervene. The gate-keeping power of committee chairs was particularly significant regarding issues that divided the majority party; for instance, during the after 1932 when the Democratic party was usually the majority in the House and Senate, committee chairs would often use their gate-keeping power to obstruct bills related to labour or race-relations (issues that created divisions between the Northern and Southern wing of the Democrats.)
ii) Proposal power: committees had the power to alter proposals or develop their own
iii) After-the –fact authority: reconciling House-Senate differences in conference committees

If committee chairs departed from the wishes of party leaders (or the President) there was very little that could be done— the seniority system made it all but impossible to punish recalcitrant chairs.

During the era of committee government, members of Congress were becoming increasingly specialized, and tended to focus their energies on a relatively small number of fields. Generalist legislators were replaced by more narrowly focused expert legislators. Why was this occurring? The volume of work undertaken by the federal government was expanding, almost exponentially, and this made specialization an attractive option. Specialization was more apparent in the House than in the Senate, simply due to their differences in size. The Senate started to rely on the more specialized committee members of the House to separate the serious legislative proposals from the not-so-serious. Increasingly, legislating in Congress was based on an agreement to respect the decisions made by other specialists; each member was concerned with a smaller and smaller sub-set of public policy, while the overall legislative and policy agenda was overseen by the President and the executive branch.

We should note that despite these changes, Congress as a legislative body remained far more influential than legislatures in parliamentary governments, where the policy-making process is dominated by cabinets and executive-branch bureaucracies. Nevertheless, the increased specialization of members of the House and Senate reflected not only the increased complexity of the national government, but also a decisive shift in favour of Presidential leadership. The President was increasingly the Chief Executive and the Chief Legislator. Different Presidents had always played a role in the legislative process, and the shift that occurred under FDR in terms of setting a legislative agenda was not necessarily a qualitative shift– though it is true that FDR was more likely than previous Presidents to not only lead and cajole Congress, but also to present very detailed legislative proposals.

More important than Presidential leadership in Congress was the kind of power demanded by the President. The President did not merely demand new laws, but instead asked Congress to delegate law-making power to the executive branch. This idea– the delegation of legislative power— is the key component of the modern state. The idea can be explained by contrasting it with the rule of law. As James Madison explains in Federalist Paper #62, a law is a rule of action; it tells you what can and cannot be done. The essential idea of the modern state is that we can no longer be governed by rules of action created by legislators; we must accept bureaucratic discretion, which means that the executive branch must be given the power to create rules of action, or perhaps even to act without any rule at all.

The delegation of discretionary power to the executive branch did not begin with the New Deal, but it certainly became more prominent. How did this affect the relationship between Congress and the Presidency? Congress became less concerned with legislating specific rules, and more concerned with how the executive branch exercises its broader, more discretionary powers. Thus, the modern state blurs the responsibilities of government– the executive branch plays a larger role in creating rules of action, and the legislative branch plays a larger role in overseeing how those rules are implemented. 64

Under “committee government,” members of Congress are increasingly specialized, and increasingly preoccupied with overseeing the executive branch. Other priorities started to change as well. Members of Congress became preoccupied with helping their constituents deal with the now more expansive and more complex federal government; constituency service took up more of their time and attention. In addition, and closely related, members of Congress became aware that decisions about where and how to spend federal money can affect their re-election prospects; thus, the most successful legislators were those most adept at directing “pork barrel” money towards their states and districts.

All of these changes created a new form of “careerism” in Congress, based upon the increased strength of the incumbency advantage. Unlike the 19th century, when Congressional elections were usually competitive, incumbents in the mid-20th century faced a less competitive electoral environment. This happened for a vast number of reasons, but we can think of this from the perspective of the incentives of the individual voter. Why might you support a candidate for the House or Senate, merely because they have been there a long time, and even if you prefer another party? Consider the effects of the seniority system. Experience has become a major resource– a key seat on a committee, or the position of committee chair, allows the representative or Senator to play a major role within Congress. To put it bluntly, power produces favors, in the form of policy and “pork.” In addition, elected officials devoted more time and energy to creating personal ties with their constituents; their experience will make them more adept at navigating the complexities of federal policy and regulation, and thus better able to provide help to their constituents.

Under “committee government,” Congress was at its greatest distance from Parliamentary government, but not merely because of the power of committee chairs and relatively autonomous committees. From the late 1930s until the 1960s, the deep divisions within the Democratic Party on questions related to race and organized labour created meant that Congress was, on these questions, effectively governed by a “conservative coalition,” even when the Democratic party was nominally in the majority.65 Consider, for instance, the following vote on the Landrum-Griffin Act66, a law which guaranteed equal rights and freedom of speech for union members, prohibited Communists and criminal from holding office within unions, and regulated various other aspects of the relationship between labor organizations and their members. The law was strongly opposed by union members, and they had some hopes that they would be able to prevent the law from passing, given the recent successes of “liberal-labor” Democrats in the 1958 election. However, the conservative coalition of Republicans and (mostly) Southern Democrats worked together to shape the content of the law.

Figure 5.6: The Conservative Coalition in Action: House Vote on Landrum-Griffin Bill, August 13th, 1959.67

Dark Red GOP “Yey”
Dark Blue Democrat “Yay”
Peach GOP “Nay”
Light Blue Democrat “Nay”

The conservative coalition did not make partisanship irrelevant during the period of committee government. For instance, Republicans and Southern conservatives tended to have very different perspectives on foreign policy, particularly during the period prior to WWII and the beginning of the Cold War. Partisanship was relatively weak, a consequence of the internal divisions within the parties themselves, divisions which were a legacy of both the Civil War and the Progressive Era. The power of “centrifugal forces” within Congress had a major effect upon policy, even though parties could be unified on many policy issues.

Three broad changes brought the era of committee government to an end. On the one hand, the Democratic Party as a whole became less tolerant of the Dixiecrat-segregationist wing of the party, which had disproportionate influence under the system of committee government. In addition, the Democratic Party began to realize that the GOP sometimes wins the Presidency, and this led to an attempt to re-energize Congress as a source of legislative leadership. Finally, the parties became more ideologically homogenous, a change which would lay the basis for increased party power within Congress. The system of committee government, in which individual members and committee chairs had a great deal of power to depart from the wishes of majorities within their own parties, was rooted in the internal ideological divisions of the Democratic party. As the Democratic party became dominated by the “liberal-labor” wing of the party, as well as the “New Left,” they took steps to reform the committee system in ways that would make things a little more difficult for ideological outliers within the Democratic party.

The system of committee government may have appeared dysfunctional in many ways. Yet it was during this period that the American Congress faced some of the most difficult challenges every faced by the nation. It is true that the decentralized character of policy-making in the House and, particularly, in the Senate, probably delayed civil rights legislation and the full integration of African-Americans into the American civil and political order. Yet despite this massive failing, the American Congress was remarkably productive during this period, and was (arguably) very responsive to majority sentiment during this period.

c) The Post-Reform System, 1970-1994

Tensions in within the “New Deal coalition” created difficulties for the Democratic Party in Congress. Since 1958, if not earlier, the Democratic Party as a whole became less tolerant of the Dixiecrat-segregationist wing of the party, which had disproportionate influence under the system of committee government. The Dixiecrats had disproportionate influence because they tended to come from non-competitive districts and states– what used to be known as the solidly Democratic south. As a consequence, Southern representatives and Senators were often overrepresented on key committees, and they were often committed, first and foremost, to preventing any federal challenges to the peculiar institutions of the racially segregated South.68 As African Americans in the north became more significant as an electoral constituency, it became much more difficult for northern Democrats to continue their strategic alliance with the Dixiecrats. The changes were obviously well underway by the 1960s– as seen in the Civil Rights Act, the Voting Rights Act, and various other policies that were meant to address the problems of racism. Yet even before then, changes in the electoral basis of the Democratic Party were creating pressure for reform of the committee system, as relatively recently elected, liberal Northern democrats were less willing to uphold the power of committee barons, who tended to be older, southern, and more conservative.

Over time, as southern Democrats started to lose to conservative Republicans, and northern Republicans began to lose to liberal democrats, the parties became more ideologically homogenous; liberal Republicans and conservative Democrats both became endangered species, though they are certainly not yet extinct. The era of committee government was initiated by divisions within the parties; as party members became more confident that they shared the same political orientation as most of their fellow party members, they became less willing to endure the power of committee barons, and more willing to grant power to party leaders within Congress.

The reforms that ended the era of Committee government took place in a number of stages, such as the Legislative Re-Organization Act of 1970 and the Democratic Caucus’ “sub-committee bill of rights” from 1973. As a consequence of these actions, committee chairs had reduced power to shape the work of committees. They could no longer use their power to kill amendments in committees without recorded votes. The seniority system for committee chairs was no longer an absolute rule; particularly after the 1974 elections, Democrats (the majority in both houses) started to select committee chairs by secret ballot69. In addition, committee chairs no longer selected sub-committee chairs. Sub-committees were given greater powers, as well as fixed jurisdiction, authority to hold their own hearings, and larger budgets and staff, all of which had previously been under the control of the committee barons. This allowed individual committee members can act on their own, or rather, it allowed them to act in conjunction with their newly hired congressional staff-members.

There was a curious dynamic occurring in the 1970s: Congress would return to some aspects of party government, but in some ways it would become even more decentralized– power moved away from key committee leaders in Congress, moving up to party leaders, and down to individual committee members. Both of these developments would help Congress take a more active stance against Presidential power– which is somewhat ironic, given that these changes would be led by the Democratic Party, which had been defined since the time of FDR by its general support for expansive executive power.

By the late 1960s, the post-New Deal Democratic Party began to realize that the GOP sometimes wins the Presidency, and this led to an attempt to re-energize Congress as a source of legislative leadership. Essentially, Congress was becoming somewhat less willing to delegate broad policy-making power to the executive branch– though given the complexity of the modern state, Congress could not really return to the pre-New Deal status quo. The increased resources (money, staff) given to individual legislators allowed Congress to play a larger role in developing laws and regulations (civil rights, environment, disability, worker safety, consumer rights, etc.) In addition, Congress made a greater effort to create specific legislative guidelines, at least in some instances. The basic problem, from the perspective of Congressional Democrats, was that they did not want to give the President broad legislative guidelines that could easily be subverted. One response was to limit Presidential discretion by creating very specific directives: instead of simply granting the federal bureaucracy the power to insure a safe workplace, Congress tried to craft specific safety regulations. But this turned out to be impossible to do on a large scale.

The second option was to make “private enforcement” of public law easier. The basic idea here is that Congress, in some instances, tried to side-step the President in the policy process by granting private groups the power to enforce public law through litigation. In many areas of law– environmental law is probably the best example– Congress would allow groups of citizens to sue private institutions for violations of law, even if those groups haven’t been directly affected. Most young people instinctively regard this as a fantastic idea, and it is easy to see why: without a doubt, it makes the political process more participatory– which can certainly be a good thing.

On the other hand, it is far from clear that Congress can delegate law enforcement power from the President to private groups. Yet given that the division of powers between the branches was hopelessly muddled in the post New Deal era, taking the additional step of inventing new forms of executive power did not seem like such an incredible stretch. In summary, Congress was using its power to “authorize” policy– the authorization process– to restrict executive discretion, either by creating more detailed law, or by creating new forms of policy implementation. We should note that despite these attempts, the President continued to have considerable power to influence policy without having to change law– that is, and still remains, one of the central features of American government in the era of the administrative state.

d) The House and Senate in a Hyper-Partisan Era 1980-2017

The long periods of divided government in the second half of the 20th century shaped the dynamics of Congress, particularly in its relationship with the executive branch. Democratic dominance of Congress, and particularly the House, was almost complete between 1955 and the 1994—and we should also note that “conservative coalition” became less and less significant over this period of time, as conservative Democrats were replaced by Republicans and the ideological centre of the Democratic Party moved to the left. During this same period, Republicans seemed to have an advantage at the Presidential level— the Democrats won only 3 of the 9 Presidential elections that occurred between 1952 and 1988, and two of those elections should probably be accorded an “asterisk” in the history books.70 Democratic control in Congress was far from complete during this period—the Republicans controlled the Senate between 1980 and 1986, and there were still significant numbers of conservative Democrats in the House. Nevertheless, Democratic support for Reagan largely vanished in the House after 1982; even though the 1980s were a period in which a conservative Republican President won two landslide elections, without being able to dislodge the Democratic Party in Congress.

What happens during extended periods of divided government, when neither party seems able to achieve unified control of the national government? On the one hand, political scientists are tempted to make predictions about the “institutional bias” of various institutions— during the 1980s and 1990s, many scholars made the claim that an era of post-electoral politics had emerged, in which Democrats were the party of Congress and the Republicans were the party of the Presidency. Unsurprisingly, institutional tensions—sometimes referred to as institutional combat—characterized this period of divided government and polarizing parties. Democratic members of Congress used their institutional prerogatives to challenge Republican appointees to the executive and legislative branches, and just as importantly, they used the power of Congressional oversight to investigate and constrain the executive branch.71

The use of congressional investigations as a political weapon is one of the best examples of institutional combat between Congress and the Presidency during the 1980s, the decade in which partisan polarization, at least amongst elites, was becoming more and more significant.72 Yet significant bi-partisan accomplishments also occurred during this period. It is true that, particularly after Reagan’s 1984 re-election, the Reagan administration focused on foreign affairs (as the Iran-Contra affair illustrates, the Reagan administration was willing to conduct foreign affairs without any regard for Congress, or even the law.) 73 Taxes remained a major focus Reagan’s domestic policy agenda. The Tax Reform Act of 1986 was, however, initiated by Democratic Senator Bill Bradley, who had made prominent criticisms of the inequities and inefficiencies of the tax code since the early years of the Reagan administration. Of course, the priorities of Republicans and Democrats were different, with Republicans more concerned with lowering tax rates, and with Democrats concerned with reducing the various loopholes that had accumulated within the tax code, a consequence of decades of interest group pressure. The bi-partisan agreement occurred because both sides were willing to bargain, and both sides wanted respond to public discontent with the policy status quo. We should also note that, in some ways, the issue of tax loopholes was in some ways unusual; the neo-liberal ideology of the Republican party led many conservatives to oppose special treatment for preferred groups and industries, while progressive Democrats opposed tax loopholes because they tended to benefit the wealthy and the powerful. Thus, it seems likely that this example of bi-partisanship during the Reagan administration depended not only upon the willingness of key members of Congress to compromise, it also depended upon the nature of the issue. 74

1994 is usually seen as a watershed year in American politics; for the first time in half a century the Republican Party assumed control of the House and the Senate. In addition to winning control of Congress, the Republican Party also modified the way Congress functioned as an institution. The parties were becoming more ideologically homogenous, and as a consequence, individual leaders were willing to concede more powers to party leaders to direct the legislative process. In 1994, led by Speaker of the House to be, Newt Gingrich, the Republicans ran a coordinated election campaign that attempted to get the electorate to think in Parliamentary terms: that is, they wanted to get voters to think of the differences between the two parties, and to focus less on the qualities of their long-serving Senator or Representative. The election of Gingrich to Speaker of the House ushered in an era– our era– where Congress is at its most “parliamentary”: members of Congress tend to vote with their parties, and they tend to defer to party leaders, that is, they tend to act like disciplined parliamentary parties.

Particularly in the House, the GOP tried to reduce the “centrifugal forces” that often complicated the legislative process. Starting in 1994, the size and number of committees were reduced, as were the number of committee staff. Term limits were placed upon the Speaker, as well as committee and sub-committee chairs. Party leaders, particularly the Speaker of the House, increased their control over the assignment process for committee membership; seniority remained the basic norm, but the Speaker was willing to violate this norm more frequently. The basic goal was to increase the power of party leaders to set the legislative agenda, and again, this power was rooted in the increased ideological unity of the parties.

It is important to note that, even in an era of ideologically homogenous parties, the American political system will always be more subject to centrifugal forces. In the era of committee government, the most important “centrifugal force” was the power of committee chairs; in the era of hyper-partisanship, the most important centrifugal force is public opinion and the ideology of individual legislators.

As in the 1980s, divided government in the 1990s produced a considerable degree of institutional combat between the Presidency and the Congress. What is particularly interesting about Congress’ investigations into the Clinton administration—the Whitewater investigations, and most memorably, the investigations associated with the Monica Lewinsky scandal—is that these investigations were not motivated by public pressure. The Republican Party was punished at the ballot box—or at the very least, derived no benefit—for delving into the various indiscretions of President Clinton. The Republicans failed to constrain institutional combat, even though they would have benefitted from paying more attention to public opinion; this provides another example of the weakness of American political parties, weaknesses that were exacerbated by ideological polarization and the broader electoral environment in the 1990s.

Despite the high profile examples of intense partisan conflict in the 1990s, President Clinton, following the pattern of the Reagan administration, was able to work with the Republican Party on small number of crucial policy issues, such as the North American Free Trade Agreement and welfare reform in 1996. While there are certain similarities between the Clinton era and the Obama era, President Obama and the Tea-Party infused Republicans do not have a successful record of bi-partisan accomplishment. The simplest explanation is that the current policy agenda does not present as many opportunities for cooperation and collaboration— which is itself a consequence of increased elite polarization.75

VII. Congress in the 21st Century: Polarization, the Legislative Process, Public Relations Wars, and Legislative Entrepreneurs

Political polarization can be defined in different ways, but in relation to Congress, it is best thought of in the simple sense of increased disagreement between the political parties across a broad range of issues. The contemporary legislative process has been shaped by political polarization in many ways. The first thing we should note is that, in the United States, the legislative process is not restricted to Congress and the President. Far more than in a parliamentary system, public opinion– and thus public relations– plays a significant part in the struggle to create law. The political scientist Barbara Sinclair has coined the term “public relations war” to describe the role played by public opinion in the American legislative process, and it is an apt term.76 Public relations wars occur as the legislative process extends into the public arena; it is waged by mobilizing public opinion, in the hopes of shaping the votes of recalcitrant legislators. These wars occur because of the weakness of political parties, something that is still relevant even during eras of great ideological polarization.

Many votes in Congress are on obscure or routine matters that do not raise much controversy; many votes are on complex matters that do not attract public attention, even if considerable inter-committee horse trading goes on when hammering the bills into shape. In regards to most controversial pieces of legislation, however, partisan conflict literally spills into the streets– or at least, the public realm– as various political actors attempt to mobilize public opinion, thereby influencing the votes of individual representatives and Senators. P.R. wars happen because, in the American system, they have a significant likelihood of being successful. Individual legislators can decide to put their individual fate above that of their party, and as a consequence, party leaders (and Presidents) have developed strategies to apply pressure the opposition and their own party members through the shaping of public opinion. Congressional parties are not the only people who take part in public relations wars– Presidents, interest groups, mass media, citizens’ organization all take part in the crazy scramble to influence public opinion, in the hopes of swaying, or insuring, congressional votes. This is when the American political bar-fight really gets going.

Public relations warfare puts some important limits on advancing legislation in the American political system, for the simple reason that no majority is ever solid, particularly on controversial issues. The best example of this is the fate of President Clinton’s health care proposals of the early 1990s– unified Democratic control of the House, Senate, and Presidency was not enough to achieve health care reform, because unified partisan control does not mean that much when individual legislators can easily defect from their parties. A slightly more recent example of this was the failure of Social Security Reform under the Bush Administration in 2005– unified partisan control was not enough to make controversial changes in a popular policy, despite the fact that Social Security in America is structured like a giant ponzi scheme.

This is interesting, because the ability to mobilize public opinion to shift votes in Congress seems to give a role to public opinion– and perhaps public demagoguery– that the framers of the Constitution did not anticipate. On the other hand, this political dynamic seems unavoidable given the current partisan environment: the strength of the two parties is relatively even, a small number of changes in votes, particularly in the Senate, can swing outcomes; Senators and representatives from highly competitive districts or states have obvious incentives to put their own electoral fortunes above the interests of their party.

Consider, for instance, the fate of climate change legislation in the American Congress during 2009 and 2010. The Obama administration pursued a relatively moderate approach to climate change, one that used market mechanisms—”cap and trade” policies—to pursue environmental goals, an approach that had been endorsed by Republicans such as 2008 Presidential candidate John McCain. What can explain the failure of climate change legislation in the Senate, if the Democrats possessed a majority, and the Obama administration was willing t court moderate Republicans?77

Geography certainly played a role. Senators from states that relied on coal power, or agricultural sectors that would have been adversely affected by the bill, were unlikely to provide support for the proposed climate change laws. Public opinion certainly played a role as well—unlike the case of welfare reform or tax reform, there was no clear public consensus in favour of reform, and thus politicians could not anticipate any clear electoral rewards for supporting it. Finally, we have to keep in mind the changed economic circumstances— the bi-partisanship of the 1980s and 1990s was difficult to maintain, despite the relative economic prosperity of those eras.

Geography and the state of the economy cannot be changed by short-term political mobilization—but is it possible to shape public opinion (and thus Congress itself) through public relations campaigns? This is another question that is difficult to answer. In the case of welfare reform in the 1990s, for instance, the battle for public opinion had been going on for decades—liberal opponents of welfare reform had lost the public relations war of 1996 long before it began.78 In the conflict over cap and trade in 2009-2010, the industries most adversely affected by the legislation were well represented in the Washington lobbying community. Yet, it may be the case that a more “level playing field” in terms of interest group resources would have affected precisely nothing.79 No amount of pro-environment lobbying can change the fact that, for instance, then-Senator Evan Bayh came from a state that was heavily reliant on coal power, or that Republican Senators, even relative moderates such as John McCain, were faced with an electorate that was more concerned with economics than the environment.

It is possible to provide a kind of minor “test” regarding the relative influence of lobbying power. What we need is a situation, an issue where a) elites in both parties support a policy change and b) the most powerful interest groups (understood in terms of money!) also support the policy change. We have a relatively recent example: the attempt of the Bush Administration, working with a Democrat controlled congress, to implement immigration reform in 2006.

The issue of immigration reform is interesting, because it is an issue that does not fall neatly into partisan categories. Left-leaning intellectuals tend to support large scale immigration, and even open borders, as a matter of principle; right-leaning corporations tend to support immigration for pecuniary motives, though their spokespersons claim to be motivated by principle as well. In 2006, immigration reform appeared to be in the same category as tax reform, welfare reform, and free trade—a policy where there was significant ideological overlap between the parties. President Bush and the leadership of the Democratic Party in Congress joined together in support of immigration reform; the public was quickly mobilized against it; 15 Democratic Senators defected from their party, and thus the reform project came to an end.

Unlike the case of environmental policy, there is no reason to think that the interest groups who favoured immigration reform were less powerful than those who opposed it. Money and lobbying are not invincible forces in the p.r. wars. Yes, in some high profile areas, such as climate change proposals and Clinton-era health, the best paid lobbyists were on the winning side. Even so, this doesn’t mean that the win was a consequence of the best paid lobbyists. “Wall Street” was hungering for a partial privatization of Social Security in 2005; but a unified GOP Congress would not give it to them; industry would love to see immigration reform, but not even a Democrat-GOP coalition could give it to them in 2006. Both cases are examples of public opinion trumping lobbying efforts.

What can we say in general about the relative ability of these forces to shape legislative outcomes in Congress? What do issues like Social Security, Health Care (in 1992-1992), and Immigration reform all have in common? These are all high profile issues that, while exceedingly complex at times, have a direct personal impact on the lives of individuals: in other words, it is relatively easy to get the public to pay attention to these issues. It is more difficult to mobilize the public regarding complex or procedural issues. For instance, in 2003, the GOP, despite having unified control over the federal government, encountered great difficulty in getting a handful of appellate court judges through the appointment process in the Senate. The problem, of course, was that GOP did not have a filibuster proof majority. The GOP made a concerted effort to mobilize the public to join in the conflict, in the hopes of undermining the determination of Democratic Senators. This effort proved to be a failure– and the reason is relatively simple. Political insiders, political activists, and political officials are all aware of the immense power held by federal appellate judges; interpretations of statutory law by federal courts can have an immense impact on public policy. For the public as a whole, however, the issue was just too arcane, not least because the public probably still holds to the quaint belief that judges are somehow above political influence. So this is an important thing to note: the mobilization of public opinion to shape Congressional votes depends very much on the kinds of issues at stake.

We have now achieved a basic overview of some of the main patterns of Congressional politics. We have seen how the internal operation of congress– the relative power of parties, committees, and individual members– shifts over time, often in response to broader changes within political parties themselves. We have seen how the operation and function of Congress is affected by the role of the President, with Congress sometimes empowering the President through broad delegations of power, and sometimes with Congress using various institutional resources to hamper, constrain, and oversee Presidential power. We have also seen how, despite partisan polarization, the relative weakness of party discipline in the American political system often causes legislative battle to spill over into the public arena in the form of “public relations wars.” We will now consider the relationship between Congress and the Presidency by returning to the concept of “delegation of legislative power.”

Congress has been uneasy with the delegation of legislative power to the President, at least since 1970s, if not earlier. The reasons for this are easy to see. If the details of law are not precisely spelled out, then the meaning of law will often change, depending upon which President sits atop the vast federal bureaucracy, overseeing the implementation and development of a vast range of rules that shape many aspects of life. Sometimes it is possible to use that discretion to not implement or develop new rules– which can be just as annoying to interested parties in Congress and elsewhere.

Yet despite being ambivalent about delegating power to the executive branch, Congress has trouble resisting the temptation. Sometimes this is because the policies in question are simply too complex to be handled by Congress directly: regarding environmental policy, work-place safety laws, and the regulation of pharmaceuticals, to name only three of the most prominent examples, Congress lacks the time and expertise necessary to create the specific, detailed rules. The real question is whether Congress nevertheless has the capacity to make the fundamental decisions regarding the principles of law, or whether delegated power is unconstrained.

On occasion, Congress delegates discretionary power to the President because members of Congress do not want to make decisions, even though they face no “technical” obstacles– consider the example of military-base closings and fast-track free trade agreements. In both cases, many members of Congress agree on the goals (closing military bases, approving specific free trade provisions) but they do not wish to be held accountable for their decisions.

Sometimes Congress delegates power to the executive branch because it feels that it lacks the ability to act quickly and decisively in times of crisis; after all, Congress was designed to act slowly and inefficiently. The story of the PATRIOT Act is a good example. While the PATRIOT Act did many things, some of its most controversial provisions increased the domestic surveillance powers of various federal law-enforcement and intelligence agencies. The law was adopted in a sort of expedited legislative process, and within months Congress had regrets, particularly about their limited oversight capacity under the new law. Yet despite many criticisms, the law was reauthorized during the Bush Administration, with bi-partisan support. This shows that while Presidents have tended to be very vigilant about many aspects of its own powers and responsibilities, Congress tends to have more serious doubts about its own capacities.

The PATRIOT Act insulated the executive branch from Congressional oversight, particularly in regards to the surveillance powers granted to the National Security Agency and the FBI. Other “emergency situations” have led to even broader delegation of unstructured power, often accompanied with a more or less open line of credit to the executive branch. The Temporary Assets and Relief Program, adopted in response to the financial crisis of 2008, gave the Secretary of the Treasury close to unlimited discretion in administering a truly mind-boggling amount of public money. Senator Jeff Sessions, R-AL and a supporter of President Bush’s war policies, observed that it “is indeed breathtaking that this Senate would authorize basically one person with very little real oversight, a Wall Street Maven himself and allocate 700 billion in America’s wealth, which I would have to say would be the largest single authorization of expenditure in the history of the Republic.” TARP was an extreme example of a general tendency in American politics: the expansion of Presidential power, unconstrained by law.

Notes

1 Thomas Mann and Norman J. Ornstein, The Broken Branch: How Congress is Failing America, and How to Get it Back on Track. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2006; Thomas Mann and Norman J. Ornstein, It’s Even Worse Than it Looks: How the American Constitutional System collided with the New Politics of Extremism. New York: Basic Books, 2012.
2 For a discussion of the role played by electoral incentives in Congress, see David Mayhew, Congress: The Electoral Connection. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 2004.
3 We leave aside the problem of minority governments.
4 Bill C-51, also known as the Anti-Terrorism Act, was passed by the Canadian Parliament in 2015.
5 The main leadership positions in the House of Representative are the Speaker of the House, the Majority and Minority leaders, and Majority and Minority whips. The Speaker of the House is the most important leadership position; unlike the Speakers in Parliamentary systems, the Speaker of the House is a partisan leader whose primary function is to insure the success of the majority party’s agenda. Though this position was established in the Constitution, the precise role of the Speaker is not spelled out in detail, and as a result the role and powers of the Speaker has changed over time. The presiding office of the Senate is the Vice President (or, if the vice president is absent, the president pro tempore, the senior member of the majority party); the partisan leadership positions in the senate are referred to as “floor leaders” or simply “Senate Majority leaders.”
6 Parties influenced candidates in the 19th century, for instance, because nominations were controlled by the party system; however, we should note that national parties were less significant here than were local and state party organizations. During some periods of time, particularly during the late 19th century, party leaders in Congress were able to exercise influence over members of Congress through their control of committee assignments. It is true that, in the contemporary era, parties often tend to vote together across a broad range of issues. This is not because of party discipline itself, if party discipline is understood as the threat of party leaders to punish disloyal members; rather, the increase in party unity votes in Congress is simply a result of the increased ideological homogeneity of the parties, and (perhaps) the homogeneity of their constituents. Individuals who share the same ideology and have broadly similar constituents tend to vote together– political scientists refer to this as the theory of conditional party government. See David Rohde, Parties and Leaders in the Post-Reform House. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991.
7 For a classic discussion of the way in which policy-making in the Canadian Parliamentary system is dominated by the Prime Minister and central agencies, see Donald Savoie, Governing from the Centre: The Concentration of Power in Canadian Politics. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1999.
9 For a discussion of the importance of descriptive representation in relation to marginalized groups, see Melissa Williams, Voice, Trust, and Memory: Marginalized Groups and the Failure of Liberal Representation. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1998.
10 See the discussion of the role of African Americans in Chicago politics in Hadley Arkes, The Philosopher in the City. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1982. It is possible that groups which exhibit too much loyalty to a particular party undermine their own potential influence within the party; if party elites know that the group will never defect from the party during elections, then there is no need for the party to prioritize the preferences of that group. See Paul Frymer, Uneasy Alliances: Race and Party Competition in America. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2010.
11 For a comprehensive survey of the first century of “ascriptive” citizenship laws in the USA (laws that restricted rights such as the right to vote on the basis of race, gender and ethnicity) see Rogers Smith, Civic Ideals: Conflicting Visions of Citizenship in U.S. History. New Haven and London: Yale University Press, 1997.
12 One could argue that Article IV, section IV “guarantee clause” of the Constitution the “guarantee clause,” which gives the federal government the power to guarantee a “republican form of government” in the states, would also allow the federal government to regulate how state limitations on voting. It is also the case that Congress has the power, under Article I, Section V, to “judge the elections, returns, and qualifications of its own members.” Thus, even absent the major constitutional amendments that addressed voting, the original Constitution gave Congress significant power to shape voting in national elections.
13 Nothing in the Constitution prevented states from granting women the right to vote; prior to the adoption of the nineteenth amendment, 30 states had already granted women the right to vote.
14 In essence, the Voting Rights Act prohibited states from adopting any voting prerequisites that created barriers to voting on the basis of race, colour, or language minority status. In addition, the law requires states to obtain “preclearance” from a federal court or the Department of Justice before changing voting regulations.
15 We should note that this was not novel; state legislature had long drawn district boundaries so as to take into account ethnic and religious communities.
16 Nicholas Stephanopolous and Eric M. McGhee, “Partisan Gerrymandering and the Efficiency Gap.” 82 University of Chicago Law Review, 2015.
19 See Bill Bishop, The Big Sort: Why the Clustering of Like-Minded Americans is Tearing us Apart. Boston: Mariner Books, 2009.
20 For documentation of the fundraising advantages of incumbents, see https://www.opensecrets.org/overview/incumbs.php?cycle=2016 Accessed November 10th, 2017.
21 Richard Fenno, Home Style: Congressmen in their Districts. Boston and Toronto: Little, Brown, and Co., 1978.
22 Markus Prior, “The Incumbent in the Living Room: The Rise of Television and the Incumbency Advantage in the U.S. House Elections.” Journal of Politics 68,3: pp 657-73
24 Amir Bera won re-election in 2016 by a margin of almost 6,000 votes.
25 For a brief summary of this issue, see Elaine Kamarck, “Increasing Turnout in Congressional Primaries.” https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/2016/06/KamarckIncreasing-Turnout-in-Congressional-Primaries72614.pdf
26 Theda Skocpol and Vanessa Williamson, The Tea Party and the Re-Making of Republican Conservatism. New York: Oxford University Press, 2012.
28 For instance, money might be a more significant electoral force in states where there are larger number of independent voters. See Nicholas Seabrook, “Money and State Legislative Elections: The Conditional Impact of Political Context.” American Politics Research. May 2010. Volume, 38 (Issue 3) pp 399-424
29 Many scholars think that the Senate is less legitimate because it is less democratic than the House or even the Presidency, yet there is no sign that this distaste for the Senate extends to the public. The public, at least today, dislikes Congress as a whole, not merely the Senate.
30 Phillip Bump, “Yes, the Senate is ignoring hundreds of bills passed by the GOP House. But it has always been that way.” Washington Post, August 6th, 2014.
31 In the 19th century, the Republican Party successfully expanded the number of small population Western states—states that were highly likely to return Republican Senators—precisely because they did not want to allow Southern states to dominate the Senate; this is why there is both a North Dakota (population of Hamilton) and a South Dakota (population of Mississauga.)
33 David Mayhew, Partisan Balance: Why Political Parties don’t kill the U.S. Constitutional System. Yale University Press: New Haven, 2011.
34 Theda Skocpol, “Naming the Problem: What it will take to counter extremism and engage Americans in the Fight Against Global Warming.” http://www.scholarsstrategynetwork.org/sites/default/files/skocpol_captrade_report_january_2013_0.pdf
35 There are several different kinds of committees:

  1. Standing Committees: These are the most important committees, and they handle almost all important legislation. The committees are permanent, their jurisdiction is usually well established, and membership on the committees tends to be stable.
  2. Select or Special Committees: committees that are appointed in response to sudden problems or emergencies that are not expected to be of permanent significance; they tend to focus on a very narrow range of issues.
  3. Joint Committees: committees made up of members of the House and Senate, usually to address relatively specialized matters. Currently there are three joint committees: The Joint Economic Committee, Joint Committee on Taxation, Joint Committee on the Library of Congress. The Joint Economic Committee is particularly important—see http://www.jec.senate.gov/public/ The Joint Economic Committee and Joint Committee on Taxation operate as advanced policy seminars for members of Congress—they do not develop legislation, but they provide a forum for sharing information and expertise.
  4. Sub-committees: Sub-committees are simply smaller sub-units of standing committees; much of the legislative and oversight work takes place within sub-committees.
  5. Conference Committees: Ad hoc committees with members from both chambers; these committees are created in order to reconcile conflicting versions bills that have been passed by the House and the Senate.
36 Congressional committees conduct legislative hearings (to acquire the information necessary to develop bills) oversight hearings (to monitor how the executive branch implements laws) and investigative hearings (which investigate various kinds of government malfeasance, particularly within the executive branch…)
37 As we will see, this was because the “seniority system,” combined with the “incumbency advantage,” gave Southern Democrats control over key leadership positions in the committee system.
38 In the Senate, the Committee on Rule and Administration is, in some ways, analogous to the Rules committee in the House. As we will see, however, the process of moving from “committee stage” to the “floor” in the Senate is subject to very different dynamics.
39 The Senate Appropriations Committee acts after the House Appropriations committee; unlike “bills for raising revenue,” this is not a Constitutional requirement.
40 The counterpart to the Ways and Means committee in the Senate is the Senate Finance Committee.
41 There are some important differences between the House and Senate Budget committees—in contrast with the House, there is no time limit placed on serving in the Senate Budget Committee. The House Budget Committee is the only committee which is limited in this way.
42 The principal-agent problem can be understood as follows: when you get someone to do a job for you, how can you insure that they do the job as you would like them to do it?
43 For a more detailed analysis of the politics of agricultural policy-making in Congressional committees, see Jay Cost, A Republic No More: Big Government and the Rise of American Political Corruption. New York and London: Encounter Books, 2015. Chapter Nine, “A Grab Bag of Subsidies: The Politics of American Agriculture.”
44 For instance, it is somewhat difficult to determine the cast of characters who devised the initial blueprint for the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act. See Morton Keller, Obama’s Time: A History. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2015.
45 For an example of the long-term politics of Congressional agenda setting in relation to welfare policy, see Steven Teles, Whose Welfare? AFDC and Elite Politics. Lawrence, Ka.: University of Kansas Press, 1996.
46 For a critique of the conventional (and easily understood) narrative that the financial crisis of 2008 was simply a “crisis of capitalism,” see Peter Wallison, Hidden in Plain Sight: What Really Caused the Financial Crisis, and Why it Could Happen Again. New York: Encounter Books, 2015.
47 Robert Kaiser, An Act Congress: How America’s Essential Institution Works, and How it Doesn’t. New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 2013. pp 112-113
48 Kaiser, An Act of Congress, chapter 7.
49 See the discussion of Gingrich and the GOP-led Congress of the 1990s in David Mayhew, America’s Congress: Actions in the Public Sphere from James Madison to Newt Gingrich. New Haven: Yale University Press, 2000. pp 235-246.
50 For a discussion of the role of individual policy entrepreneurs in the legislative process, see Craig Volden and Alan E. Wiseman, “Entrepreneurial Politics, Policy Gridlock, and Legislative Effectiveness.” in Jeffery A. Jenkins and Eric M. Patashnik, ed. Congress and Policy-Making in the 21st Century. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2016 pp 21-47
51 Barbara Sinclair, Unorthodox Legislation: New Legislative Processes in the U.S. Congress. Thousand Oaks, Ca.: Sage/CQ Press, 2017. p. 51
52 Sinclair, Unorthodox Legislation
53 For a discussion of the “informational model” and “gains from trade/preference outlier” models of committee behavior, see Charles Stewart III, Analyzing Congress. New York: W.W. Norton, 2012. pp 339-352.
54 Robert G. Kaiser, An Act of Congress. New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 2013. Chapter 13 “In the Weeds” and Chapter 14 “Making Sausage.”
55 Kaiser, An Act of Congress, pp 176-178.
56 According to contemporary judicial doctrine, federal law only preempts state law if Congress makes an explicit decision to do so. Michael Greve, The Upside-Down Constitution. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 2012 pp 213-214
57 The question of the relative expertise of committee members is related to the broader question of “what makes an individual legislator effective or successful?” For a recent exploration of this, see Craig Volden and Alan E. Wiseman, Legislative Effectiveness. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2014.
58 David W. Brady, Revolving Gridlock: Politics and Policy from Jimmy Carter to George W. Bush. Boulder, CO.: Westview Press, 2006.
59 See David Mayhew, The Imprint of Congress. New Haven: Yale University Press, 2017.
60 “Cap and trade” laws are one way to reduce green-house gas emissions. These types of laws give pollution permits to companies, which can then be sold to other companies, thereby giving the companies an incentive to reduce their own emissisons.
61 For more information of this vote, see https://voteview.com/rollcall/RH0610083
62 “Congressional hearings” refers to the process through which Congress obtains and analyzes information in the early stages of the legislative process, typically through oral testimony and questioning. In addition to legislative hearings, Congress also conducts “oversight hearings” (to oversee the operation of the executive branch), “confirmation hearings” (conducted by the Senate prior to high-level Presidential appointments), “investigative hearings” (to investigate particular scandals on malfeasances on the part of government officials) and “ratification hearings” (held in the Senate prior to consideration of international treaties.)
63 “Mark-up” refers to the process in which congressional committees debate and amend a bill within the committee.
64 For analysis of the politics of Congressional delegation, see Jasmine Farrier, Congressional Ambivalence: The Political Burdens of Constitutional Authority. Louisville: University of Kentucky Press, 2010.
65 The “conservative coalition” was not the first time that a bi-partisan coalition was able to control the policy agenda within Congress, of course. During the 1920s, for instance, a “farm bloc” within Congress (composed on Southern Democrats and mid-western, mostly progressive Republicans) were able to shape American agriculture policy, contrary to the wishes of the Republican leadership who wanted a “return to normalcy” after the experience with massive government economic intervention in World War One. See Eric Schickler, Disjointed Pluralism: Institutional Innovation and the Development of the U.S. Congress. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2001.
66 The official title is the “Labor Management Reporting and Disclosure Act of 1959.” Public Law-86 257.
67 This was not the final vote on the bill. Rather, it was a vote on a bill which two conservative representatives, Phil Landrum(D-GA) and Robert Griffin (R-MI) had introduced to replace an anti-corruption bill reported from the House Education and Labor Committee. The Landrum-Griffin bill had much stronger provisions related to secondary boycotting and organizational picketing. For a discussion of this issue, and issues related to the conservative coalition and labour policy in the USA, see Tracy Roof, American Labor, Congress, and the Welfare State, 1935-2010. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 2011. pp75-78
68 See, for instance, Keith M. Finley, Delaying the Dream: Southern Senators and the Fight Against Civil Rights, 1938-1965. Baton Rouge: Louisiana State University Press, 2008.
69 With the decline of the old Southern Democrats, however, the Democratic Party has tended to place more emphasis upon seniority than the Republicans.
70 The election of JFK in 1960 was extremely close—well within “the margin of fraud.” The election of 1976 was a clean win for the Democratic Party, but it was under very unusual circumstances (President Nixon had been utterly disgraced by the Watergate affair) and the victory was far from overwhelming.
71 One study of Congressional investigations from 1947-2010 found that two of the three Congresses which conducted the largest number of investigations of the executive branch occurred during the Reagan administration—1981-1982 (73 investigations) and 1983-1984 (47 investigations); the third highest number of investigations took place in the final two years of the George W. Bush administration (41 investigations) which was also a period of divided government.
72 We should note that investigations are a somewhat cumbersome tool. To paraphrase the most prominent theory about congressional investigations and executive branch oversight, Congress acts like a fire-fighter, not a policy-officer, when overseeing and investigating the executive branch. Congress could spend a good deal of time watching and “patrolling” the executive branch, but this is costly in terms of time—time that could be better spend writing laws, taking to mass media, dealing with constituents, raising money, and so on. Instead, Congress tends to investigate when “fire alarms” have been set off—by interest groups, media reports, bureaucratic leaks, and so on.
74 Timothy J. Conlan, Margaret T. Wrightson, David R. Beam, Taxing Choices: The Politics of Tax Reform. Washington D.C.: Congressional Quarterly Press, 1990
75 We should note that Obama has worked with House and Senate Republicans on trade related initiatives, such as the Trans-Pacific partnership. Trade is one of the policy areas where there is a significant overlap between the parties. The major reforms of the Reagan and Clinton era occurred in a time of strong economic growth; in regards to tax reform, there were no ideological differences between the parties; in regards to welfare reform, while the Democratic Party was deeply divided over the question, moderate Democrats such as Clinton had much in common with their Republican counter-parts—Clinton even made “ending welfare as we know it” a theme of his 1992 election campaign.
76 Barbara Sinclair, Party Wars: Polarization and the Politics of National Policy-Making. Norman, Ok.: Oklahoma University Press, 2006.
77 The House voted 219-212 in favour of the Waxman-Markey “American Clean Energy and Security Bill” on June 29th, 2009. 8 Republicans supported the bill, while 44 Democrats opposed it.
78 See the discussion in Steven M. Teles, Whose welfare?: AFDC and elite politics. Lawrence: University Press of Kansas, c1996.
79 Measuring the “power” of interest groups in this particular public relations war is an immensely difficult task. One thing we should note is that environmentalist interest were well represented, not least because many corporations were in favour of the legislation. For a discussion of one of the most important interest group organizations that participated in the P.R. war of Waxman-Markey, see http://www.sourcewatch.org/index.php/Climate_Action_Partnership

License

The American Congress and the Legislative Process Copyright © 2018 by Ryan Hurl and Hurl, Ryan, et al.. All Rights Reserved.

Share This Book